Whether you’re mapping the universe, hosting a late-night talk show, or running a meeting, there are a lot of ways to up your idea game. Plus: the truth about brainstorming. (Ep. 3 of the “How to Be Creative” series.)
Category: Uncategorized
-
#52 Dr. Laura Markham: Peaceful Parenting with
Parenting expert and multiple best-selling author Dr. Laura Markham breaks down the three keys to successful discipline, how to properly model emotions and conflict resolution, and the coveted recipe for raising happy, resilient kids.
Go Premium: Members get early access, ad-free episodes, hand-edited transcripts, searchable transcripts, member-only episodes, and more. Sign up at: https://fs.blog/membership/
Every Sunday our newsletter shares timeless insights and ideas that you can use at work and home. Add it to your inbox: https://fs.blog/newsletter/
Follow Shane on Twitter at: https://twitter.com/ShaneAParrish
-
E25: We are the Burnout Generation
This week has been chaotic. In Chapter Five of The Diary of a CEO I flew back to the UK for an incredibly busy week filled with podcast interviews, speaking appointments, pitching to one of our biggest clients as well as filming an advert campaign. The …
-
a16z Podcast: Gaming Goes Mainstream
AI transcript
0:00:04 Hi everyone, welcome to the A6NC podcast.
0:00:07 Today’s episode features Mark Andreessen interviewing Bobby Kotick,
0:00:12 CEO of Fortune 500 company Activision Blizzard, the largest game network in the world,
0:00:17 responsible for popular entertainment franchises such as Call of Duty, Candy Crush and World of
0:00:23 Warcraft. The discussion originally took place at our most recent annual innovation summit
0:00:28 and covers everything from the evolution of games in the 80s to the mergers and acquisitions that
0:00:33 created the company he runs today to trends in gaming, including touching on esports.
0:00:40 You can also find other podcasts and videos from this event at asixnz.com/summit.
0:00:45 Please note that the content here is for informational purposes only, should not be taken as legal
0:00:51 business tax or investment advice, or be used to evaluate any investment or security.
0:00:55 For more details, please also see asixnz.com/disclosures.
0:00:59 So, Bobby, it is really fun as a long-time video game aficionado. Really fun to have the chance
0:01:05 to talk to you today. I would love to start with your origin story, as they say in the superhero
0:01:09 business. So, part of your origin story, if I recall correctly, is that you started writing
0:01:14 software for the Apple II while you were still in college. So, my college roommate and I started
0:01:19 a company. He worked at Apple Computer in France. He was French and his summer internship,
0:01:25 he was working for a guy called Jean-Louis Gasset, and they had a prototype of the Lisa,
0:01:30 and the Lisa was the Mac before the Mac. It was the $10,000 version of the Mac.
0:01:38 So, he saw this prototype of the Lisa and thought for $10,000 this would be too expensive to turn
0:01:44 into a consumer product. So, he came back from his internship and said, “We should make Lisa-like
0:01:50 software and a mouse for the Apple II.” And we were in another sort of technology-related
0:01:54 business in our dorm room at the time, but we thought we were making hardware. I thought this
0:01:59 would be a better business, is make software. And we really thought if Steve Jobs is going to
0:02:04 appropriate all the great technology from Xerox Palo Alto Research Center, we should do the same,
0:02:11 but do it on a broader scale. So, we designed this mouse and a word processor and a spreadsheet
0:02:17 and a database all for the Apple II with a graphical user interface about a year before
0:02:21 the Macintosh was released. You also, I believe, credit, if I’m correct, Steve Jobs with convincing
0:02:25 you to drop out of college? I don’t know if it’s credit, but Steve Jobs heard about us.
0:02:29 Because when you started, you were in college. I was in college. I was making Apple II software,
0:02:36 and he heard about the software, and he called me and said, you know, the lady said, “Steve Jobs
0:02:40 calling.” I was like, “Okay, it’s one of the kids I grew up with from Rosalind Long Island, and this
0:02:46 is not even that good a joke.” Steve is like super famous, like Cover Time magazine. Yeah, this is
0:02:54 like 1983, late 1983. ’83, ’83, ’83. Right. Super famous. Yeah, and I’m like, “Yeah, right, whatever.”
0:02:59 So, I pick up the phone, he’s like, “Hi.” I said, “Hi.” He said, “This is Steve Jobs.” I said,
0:03:03 “Yeah.” Sure. And all I’m thinking is like, I wanted to say like, “I’m Oscar Robertson.” I was
0:03:09 a big Knicks fan. I thought like, so he starts like telling me, “You need to come to Cupertino,
0:03:14 and I really want to talk to you about this Jane thing that you made.” And so I go, and he shows
0:03:20 his prototype of the Macintosh, and like, I’ll never forget this moment. He unzips this little blue
0:03:24 bag from off of his table, and he takes it out, and he turns it on, and you see the hell out come
0:03:28 up on the screen, and I thought, “Wow, this is unbelievable. This is going to change computing.”
0:03:33 And I like, I still get the goosebumps of just thinking about it. And then he said, “Okay, now
0:03:40 show me yours.” And so like, I’ve had lugged this Apple II with like the 64K floppy drive,
0:03:44 and this mouse that we designed, and we put it on, and I show him the mouse, and he looks at it,
0:03:51 he’s like, “This is a piece of shit.” And he throws it on the floor, and he says, “You’re going to use
0:03:54 our mouse, and don’t ever think of using a two-button mouse. You’re going to use a one-button
0:03:59 mouse.” And then I show it to him, and the first thing he says is, “Wait a second. You select the
0:04:03 text, and then you select boldface?” I’m like, “Yeah.” He’s like, “No. We’re going to think about
0:04:08 verb noun versus noun verb in the way you actually boldface type.” And for 45 minutes, we had this
0:04:13 huge debate about how you boldface type. And at the end of it, he’s like, “You’re going to make
0:04:17 this for a new computer that we’re going to build called the Apple II GS, and we’re going to tell
0:04:21 you all about it, but you’re going to make this software for the Apple II. And we’re going to
0:04:27 give you a contract.” He goes, “This is a contract.” And then he comes to visit us in Ann Arbor,
0:04:35 Michigan, in our office above a Burger King. And the first thing he says is, “How the hell do you
0:04:43 work here? The smell of burgers comes up the elevator.” He’s like, “It was cheap rent. Nobody
0:04:49 else wanted to rent on top of a Burger King.” So at the end of the meeting, he says, “Do you have
0:04:56 any vegetarian restaurants here that we could go to for dinner?” And I said, “Yeah, I’m sure we do,
0:05:01 but I can’t go to dinner. I have a class.” He’s, “What do you mean?” I said, “I have a class.” He
0:05:06 said, “In what?” I said, “It’s a history of art makeup class.” He said, “What are you making up for?”
0:05:11 I said, “Well, I didn’t go to the class.” He’s like, “Well, why do you need to go to this?” I said,
0:05:17 “Well, I’m in college.” And he looks at me. He’s like, “What are you talking about? You have a
0:05:21 contract with Apple Computer, and we have a deadline for the Apple II GS. You can’t be in
0:05:25 college. You have employees. You have to work full-time.” He’s like, “Get out of college.”
0:05:30 And I said, “I can. I promise my parents I would finish college.” He said,
0:05:36 “No, you’re not finishing college. I will rip,” and I can’t say the word,
0:05:41 “I will rip this f-ing contract up right now if you don’t quit college.” So I quit the next day.
0:05:47 Did your parents believe the story? I didn’t tell them for about eight months. I felt like,
0:05:51 all right, I needed to get more progress in the business before my father would say,
0:05:56 “You’re an idiot. Now, you took money from this gambling guy and you quit college. You’re just a
0:06:04 loser.” So then fast forward a few years. So 1990, you bought 25% stake in Activision,
0:06:09 became CEO in 1991. So Activision, people may not know, Activision was a storied brand in video
0:06:13 games. Activision, I believe this is correct, was the first third-party developer of video games
0:06:19 in 1980. So it was a spin-off from Atari. It was for the top people at Atari. They got in
0:06:22 conflict with management. And this is a very big deal, number one, just because, you know, to quit
0:06:25 starting a company is a big deal. But also it’s just a big deal because like literally there had
0:06:29 not been a business of making video games for somebody else’s platform. Atari made all the
0:06:33 games for Atari. And now at this company, Activision, they had a run of hits, I guess in the 80s,
0:06:37 early 80s, you know, they made a bunch of the top games for Atari systems. And then they went
0:06:41 bankrupt or they were about to go bankrupt. They had a decade of pathetic performance and then
0:06:46 finally went bankrupt. Okay, got it. So as long as a whimper, not a bang. And so how did you get
0:06:53 from building mice in your above the Burger King to buying Activision? So in 1987, there were no
0:06:59 real video game hardware companies. And I played a lot of video games as a kid and I loved Activision
0:07:05 games. So they made the original Atari 2600 games that made the company so successful. Games like
0:07:12 Pitfall and River 8 and Kaboom. And these are just great games. And so in 1987, I thought there’s a
0:07:18 great opportunity to make video game hardware. And nobody is making video game hardware games are
0:07:24 just played on personal computers. Nintendo was just coming to the US. So there was no
0:07:31 dedicated video game hardware. My best friend from growing up had just started a hedge fund
0:07:36 with this guy from Texas named Richard Rainwater. And they were looking for investments.
0:07:42 And I went to him and I said, I have this idea. And in 1987, in October, the market had crashed.
0:07:46 It was like a 500 point market crash was Black Monday. Black Monday was one of the
0:07:53 biggest crashes in the market history since the Great Depression. And I had been working
0:07:58 making software for, among other companies, Apple and Commodore. And Commodore was this
0:08:06 $900 million revenues company at the time with $150 million market value. And so I went to
0:08:10 my best friend and I said, we should buy Commodore. They have this computer called the Amiga.
0:08:14 And it has a keyboard and a disk drive, but we should pull the keyboard and the disk drive out of
0:08:20 it. And it would be the first 16 bit video game system. And it was designed by Exitari engineers
0:08:25 and was made basically as a video game. It was a big leap forward graphics performance at the time.
0:08:31 68,000 microprocessor and dedicated graphics processors. And it was like a really innovative
0:08:39 idea. And my best friend at the time said, yeah, let’s try and do this. And so we tried. And
0:08:45 ultimately couldn’t persuade the chairman of Commodore to do the deal. But I just became then
0:08:53 fixated with being in the video game business. And my best friend at the time was Eddie Lampert,
0:08:57 who then went on instead of buying Commodore to buy Sears and Kmart. And he was a customer for a
0:09:04 little while. We stopped extending credit to him. I think four years ago, though. So I thought, okay,
0:09:10 we have to be in the video game business. And I had a little side business that was a licensing
0:09:18 company. We licensed characters. So one of our licensing partners was Nintendo. And we were
0:09:25 licensing Nintendo characters for bedsheets and lunchboxes. And I knew the Nintendo people. And
0:09:30 one day I was having a Nintendo meeting. And they said, have you ever thought about
0:09:35 Activision? And I said, yeah, I know the company well, I played all the games. And they said,
0:09:39 they’re not in really good shape. And they’re about to lose a patent infringement judgment that
0:09:47 will probably make them bankrupt. So you should consider buying Activision. So I bought a 25%
0:09:53 stake in Activision for $440,000. And I became the largest shareholder.
0:10:00 And it was insolvent. But I tried to get the CEO on the phone to tell him I was his new largest
0:10:04 shareholder. It’s a public company. It’s a public company with a market cap of $1.6 million. Yeah,
0:10:12 $1.6 million. And a patent infringement judgment that made it insolvent. And so I couldn’t… Here’s
0:10:17 this company that’s doing horribly, has all these great franchises. And the CEO wouldn’t return my
0:10:22 phone call. And so I kept calling, kept calling. And finally I just thought, I’ll just go to the lobby
0:10:29 of the building and tell him I’m there and see if he’ll see me. So I go and I’m waiting in the lobby.
0:10:34 And finally after three hours, he says, okay, I’ll come talk to you. And I talked to him and I
0:10:37 said, you know, we’re your largest shareholder. I have some really great ideas for you. I have
0:10:42 some game ideas I’d like to make. And, you know, I love some of the old properties. Maybe we can
0:10:47 figure out how to really get some of those properties back to being games. And he’s like,
0:10:52 well, thank you very much for visiting and nice to meet you. And I said, no, no, I’m like, when is
0:10:58 the next meeting? And he said, there’s not a next meeting, but we’re very happy to have you as
0:11:05 shareholders. And so I thought, well, how does that work? I own 25% of the company. I’m the
0:11:10 largest shareholder. We’re really a quarter of the furniture in the lobby. And he didn’t return my
0:11:14 phone calls for a little while. And then he agreed to have breakfast with me at this consumer
0:11:19 electronic show in Las Vegas. Obviously, Activision was then, you know, tremendously successful.
0:11:23 You then did one other really, really big deal that was transformative for the company, which was
0:11:27 and I don’t quite know how to describe it, but I think it’s a merger with Vivendi games
0:11:31 that resulted in Activision Blizzard, because Vivendi owned Blizzard, Blizzard, obviously,
0:11:35 World of Warcraft and all these other amazing properties. And then ultimately that partnership
0:11:38 on one, maybe you could tell us like that was a very, very big deal for you at the time.
0:11:44 How did that deal come about? So it was the spring of 2008. And I had a lot of anxiety about the
0:11:50 public markets and financial crisis is brewing. Yeah. And you could see there was a lot of
0:11:55 volatility instability. We were nervous, but we thought, you know, if we could buy something,
0:11:59 we had a big market value at the time. And I thought if we could buy something great,
0:12:04 that we really love, this would be a good time to do it. And you guys weren’t yet doing the massive
0:12:08 multiplayer. You guys weren’t yet doing like there was this big World of Warcraft had been a big hit
0:12:14 at that point. Huge hit. And we had explored doing a massively multiplayer persistent game.
0:12:19 There were a couple of other games before World of Warcraft that were massively multiplayer games,
0:12:25 but nothing that had had the success of WoW. And we looked and said, if we even could figure out
0:12:31 how to do it, it would take us five, six, seven years and a billion dollars. And the likelihood is
0:12:36 we wouldn’t do a good job of it. But it was a, and I knew the Blizzard team because we had worked
0:12:42 with them on, they were a contract development company in the early 1990s. And I knew the team
0:12:48 very well and really liked them. And I tried to recruit them out of the company. And I knew that
0:12:52 they had so much of a love and a passion for the company that no matter who owned it, they probably
0:12:57 wouldn’t leave. And I called the guys at Blizzard a bunch of times and said, we should truly try and
0:13:03 work this out. And they were stuck as a division of Vivendi Games, which was owned by Vivendi.
0:13:10 And you might describe what Vivendi was at this point. It was a big mess. And it was a former,
0:13:15 if I think it’s correct, it was a former public utility. Well, it was the water company of France
0:13:20 that this very, and by water and other things that flow through pipes. Yeah, water, other things that
0:13:26 flow through pipes. It was a collection of more industrial businesses that the, a man had taken
0:13:32 it over and decided he was going to become the media mogul of earth and bought universal studios.
0:13:38 And anything he could actually buy, he just bought. And then it got disassembled because
0:13:44 it was insolvent. And they ended up with a couple of businesses. The best one for them at the time
0:13:51 was probably Universal Music, which I think Lucine is here somewhere. So they had Universal Music.
0:13:58 They owned Morocco Telecom, Upstake. They owned SFR, which is a French mobile company.
0:14:04 They own Kennel Police. And somehow they managed as a part of a bunch of things to own
0:14:10 this games business, which included Blizzard. And I asked them to sell us Blizzard. And we didn’t
0:14:14 have any interest in the rest of their games business, but we wanted Blizzard. And they said,
0:14:20 no, repeatedly. And we offered them $4 billion and then $5 billion and then $6 billion and then $7
0:14:25 billion. They kept saying, no, they like video games. So we came up with this idea and we said,
0:14:31 how about this? We’ll stay a public company. You sell us Blizzard or give us Blizzard and $2
0:14:38 billion of cash, and we’ll give you 51% of the company. And my view was in 2008, even the biggest
0:14:45 institutional investors no longer were really long-term holders. And all the big institutional
0:14:49 investors were trading in and out of the stocks like they were hedge funds. So if we could get
0:14:56 Vivendi to own 51% of our company, we got Blizzard as a partner, we would have a great business and
0:15:01 a stable shareholder who would never sell our stock and would be enthusiastic about investing,
0:15:07 at least what they told us, investing with us for the future. So we went back and forth for a
0:15:13 long time, finally negotiated a deal where they would do that deal. And I almost blew the deal
0:15:19 in the worst way too. They had this beautiful headquarters in France, like the nicest building
0:15:23 in France. And the guy who had put the original Vivendi together, there were lots of these
0:15:29 beautiful French offices that had gardens on the top of their roof. He built a park
0:15:36 and like mature trees on the top of the Vivendi building. It was like a park with trees that
0:15:41 were all over the place. And one room was like a wine cellar and one room was this magnificent
0:15:46 dining room. And so we’re standing on the top of this roof overlooking the Arc de Triomphe
0:15:54 and the Eiffel Tower. And the chairman of the Vivendi says to me, “Bobby, this building,
0:15:59 it will be your home. This will be your place. You can do your business in France and you should
0:16:03 treat this building like your home. You can do anything you want with this building, but it will
0:16:08 be your place for Paris. You can make a business here. And it’s the most beautiful building in
0:16:13 Paris. It’s the most beautiful view in Paris and it’s for you. You can do anything you want with
0:16:19 it.” And I said, “Anything? You can do anything.” And I said, “Can I build 20 stories of condominiums?”
0:16:26 And he turned white and I could see the like, “Oh my God, who are we getting in business with love?”
0:16:31 I was going to say, “He hadn’t been briefed.” And I said, “No, no, Jean-Marie, I’m just kidding.
0:16:37 We would only build 10 stories.” But he still went through with the deal. And so we had five
0:16:45 wonderful years with them as our 51% shareholder until they were forced to sell our stake. But it
0:16:49 was the thing that actually allowed us to acquire a business. So it’s a big deal. I mean, it’s really
0:16:53 uncharacteristic for a company like this with a founder really of the modern business and then a
0:16:57 CEO like you to be willing to sign over control. So that story to me makes a lot of sense if you’d
0:17:05 said 49%. What was it about that deal that made you willing to literally sign up? Because it
0:17:09 worked out well with that. Was it a pretty big risk at the time or not? I didn’t really think I
0:17:16 was selling control. I think I was selling 51%, but I thought they really know nothing about video
0:17:22 games. What are they going to do? And I don’t think they’re going to interfere all that much. I was
0:17:26 actually wrong. They didn’t really have, you know, it’s like a corporate holding company. So they
0:17:32 were always trying to justify their value as a corporate holding company. And you know, we had
0:17:38 like, I remember the, and Lucien who’s here will attest to this is exactly what happened. But
0:17:43 they said we’re having a synergy meeting and all the business unit heads need to come together
0:17:50 for the synergy meeting. Now they own a stake in Morocco telecom. We didn’t do business in Morocco.
0:17:56 They own SFR, the French telephone company and mobile games wasn’t really a thing at that time.
0:18:01 They own Canal Plus. So a French TV network didn’t really have any applicability and
0:18:06 universal music where we did license some music for Guitar Hero, but other than that we had no
0:18:11 relationship and a broadband company in Brazil. So we all get together and have this big synergy
0:18:15 meeting. And then we had to go around the room and say the synergies that we identified between
0:18:23 each other. And they got to me and I said that Morocco telecom, we went to their cafeteria
0:18:30 and they have tagine. And we got the tagine recipe for our cafeteria,
0:18:42 which I thought was a great synergy because I like tagine, but there wasn’t really that much
0:18:48 synergy. So then they had to sell us back their stake. And then it was completely unwinding,
0:18:53 ultimately. And I guess they completely unwound in their own way. And everybody did well.
0:18:57 So it turned out. So give us a kind of a state of the video games industry today,
0:19:03 gigantic global phenomenon, lots and lots of change and flux, lots of potential controversy.
0:19:09 So I would say of the 28 years I’ve been doing Activision, 30-some-odd years I’ve been doing
0:19:16 software, I’ve never seen more opportunities than exist today. Markets that are opening. And you
0:19:22 think just 10 years ago, if you wanted to play video games, you either needed $1,000 PC or $300
0:19:27 or $400 video game console. And there really weren’t any other ways to play video games. But
0:19:34 phones have ushered in this whole new opportunity. And like for years, for most of the tenure that
0:19:41 I’ve had as CEO, we sold in developed countries to middle-class consumers on expensive devices.
0:19:47 Today, we sell in 196 countries around the world. We have 400 million customers.
0:19:56 And anyone in any socioeconomic strat can actually play games. I think that was the biggest shift
0:20:01 that took place is now you truly have a global market. The second thing that then happened is
0:20:08 when you started to see the games become more social experiences. I can use a headset. I can
0:20:12 talk to the person I’m playing with. I can play with somebody from anywhere around the world.
0:20:19 The introduction of the social experience was the true transformation to me of the opportunity.
0:20:24 And so where you look out in the world today, you have a global audience. You have this ability
0:20:31 to create this true social experience. And I remember years ago hearing this, and I’ll paraphrase,
0:20:36 but Mandela had this definition of sport, that it was the great equalizer. And it was this thing
0:20:42 that allowed you to actually break racial barriers and religious barriers and economic barriers in
0:20:48 order to foster competition and that the great competitors in sport could come from anywhere.
0:20:53 And everybody felt this ability to have a sense of belonging and purpose and meaning. And that
0:21:00 is what video games has become for so many people. And it’s hard to illustrate this for some people,
0:21:05 but I was at a panel not long ago with Alex Rodriguez, who actually owns one of our Overwatch
0:21:13 team franchises, and Roger Goodell, who is the NFL commissioner. And the moderator said, “Are eSports
0:21:20 sports?” And I said, “The same characteristics that Mandela described, what makes sport great
0:21:26 is what makes eSports so compelling and engaging.” And I said, “To Alex, stand up.”
0:21:34 And Alex stood up and I said, “Look at you. How many people in the world can play professional
0:21:38 baseball?” And he said, “Well, there are roughly 1,200 professional baseball players in the
0:21:45 Major League Baseball and about 3,000 capable of playing Major League Baseball.” And I said,
0:21:52 “Look at this guy. Like this is like the most fit athletic specimen of a human on the earth.
0:21:58 And there are only 3,000 of those people who can do what he does. Video games is the only
0:22:03 competitive medium that is going to give me that experience and that purpose and that sense of
0:22:07 belonging and that camaraderie that you get from sport.” And so, of course, it’s going to be
0:22:13 as popular as sport, if not more popular than sport. And that, I think, more than anything, is now
0:22:19 what we see as driving consumption and engagement and interest and passion. And we’re just scratching
0:22:24 the surface of opportunity. So I think people have obviously had a lot of great experiences
0:22:27 and a great faith in the video game industry for many years, based on the idea that everybody
0:22:32 can participate. This idea that people are going to voluntarily watch other people playing video
0:22:37 games is a new idea. And obviously it’s becoming a twitch and one of our companies and so forth.
0:22:42 Like this is going to be a very big phenomenon. It’s a key part of eSports is the ability to
0:22:45 fill an arena with people watching other people play video games. Like a few years ago,
0:22:50 that just sounded wildly implausible. What was the point? Like, when did you figure that out?
0:22:55 Well, I think probably when we launched. I didn’t own Blizzard at the time, but when Starcraft
0:23:00 launched, this was a game that in Korea, I think at the height of its popularity. Rob’s here,
0:23:05 so he’ll know the exact number. But I think, you know, this is more than a decade ago, but the
0:23:11 height of its popularity in Korea, Starcraft had 5 million registered players. Now this is a country
0:23:18 of 60 million people. The game is primarily a male game experience. And so you think about 20% of
0:23:24 the population actually of the male population played, or was a registered player of Starcraft.
0:23:30 And we saw arenas getting filled with spectators. There were three dedicated cable channels in
0:23:34 South Korea that just broadcast Starcraft competition. There were sponsors. There were
0:23:40 professional players making $100,000 or more. So this is an amazing phenomena that took place that
0:23:45 we looked at as purely marketing. You know, the people are enthusiastic. We saw the box. There was
0:23:51 nothing more to it than that. And we managed to do every single thing wrong in commercializing the
0:23:58 eSport of Starcraft. But it was the first time where I really thought, you know, there’s something
0:24:04 that could even be bigger than the games themselves that would relate to the spectator experience.
0:24:10 Now, even with games like Overwatch, which is probably our most successful eSport initiative,
0:24:16 it’s more like golf. So if you’re a spectator of Overwatch, it’s likely you’re a player of
0:24:24 Overwatch. Fortnite, I think, was the first game where people would spectate and it would actually
0:24:30 be a catalyst for them to play. And so I think what’s happened is it’s more of a social experience
0:24:35 in a lot of respects than it is just a game. But I think that what you’re now starting to see is
0:24:41 that games have so infiltrated the popular culture of the world that it’s exciting for people to watch
0:24:45 their heroes who compete against each other in the same way as sport.
0:24:50 Right. So many of the most successful games that people watch or that are now actually
0:24:53 formerly eSports, correct me if I’m wrong, they were not originally designed for this
0:24:56 period. They were designed to be games that people just played and they’ve been kind of repurposed
0:25:00 into this kind of broader public phenomenon. Maybe that’s to play untrue, but I guess my question
0:25:06 is kind of how will video games be designed going forward for eSports and for people watching it in
0:25:10 addition to playing that is different than how video games have been designed up to this point?
0:25:14 Yeah, that’s a great question. So a lot of the games today were not specifically designed for
0:25:21 spectating, which is why you end up with that phenomenon of the players are the spectators.
0:25:29 In order to have a more broad appeal spectator experience, the games need to be designed in a
0:25:33 way that you actually want to watch them, whether you do or don’t play them. And I would say that
0:25:40 the Overwatch team spent a lot of time early on trying to construct a game from the ground up
0:25:45 that would be a fun spectator experience. But I think what you will see is that people are now
0:25:51 paying more attention to in game design, the idea that the games may be spectated by people who
0:25:56 aren’t players. I don’t think anytime soon that’s going to be the primary consideration. We’ll still
0:26:05 be principally focused on gameplay, but things like camera angles and commentating and making sure
0:26:10 like when we organized the Overwatch League, one of the organizing principles was the reason why
0:26:17 sports are so successful is tribalism and that having a local affiliation was so crucial to the
0:26:22 success of sport, whether it’s a country affiliation or city affiliation. So we created a structure
0:26:29 that allowed for 28 independent cities to field teams. And I think that as you start to take those
0:26:34 considerations into play when you’re thinking about the design of the games or the leagues or the
0:26:39 competitive experience, that they will have more of the characteristics of traditional sport.
0:26:42 Right. Would you venture a guess as to when video games will be in the Olympics?
0:26:46 Which is a logical implication of what we’re discussing, right?
0:26:51 I don’t think so. I actually don’t think like the Olympics has never been about
0:26:57 a commercial enterprise. And so if you think of the analog, right, there’s not like if you had to
0:27:04 pick a game, you’re now endorsing someone’s commercial enterprise. You know, there’s not any,
0:27:11 there’s they don’t have that analog today. And so I don’t know that you could see the logical
0:27:16 jump to the Olympics. Okay. The video game industry seems to have a particularly cute version of a
0:27:21 dynamic that you see with, you know, let’s just say consumer properties that inspire an avid fandom.
0:27:24 So it’s the enthusiastic early adopters, right? And so you see this with movies,
0:27:28 you see this with TV shows, you see this with basically things that really occupy the popular
0:27:33 imagination. You know, for sure see it with video games. So you’ve got this kind of leading edge,
0:27:38 you might say early adopters slash super enthusiastic user base, and they start to develop
0:27:42 opinions and they start to develop opinions that maybe the people who make the games are quite
0:27:46 doing what they want. And then when things, you know, really go sideways, there can be, you know,
0:27:50 protestant boycoss and all kinds of like, you can end up with the inmates running the asylum or at
0:27:54 least looking like they’re certainly trying to, how do you throw the needle as somebody who make
0:27:58 an overseas letters? How do you how do you throw the needle for the early adopter base as opposed to
0:28:02 the mainstream? And how much is the early adopter base an asset? How much is the early adopter base
0:28:08 a challenge, a problem? So I think that the difference between film or television, you know,
0:28:14 a great film, you’re going to spend two hours of your life watching. You know, great TV shows,
0:28:20 it’s going to be 13 episodes or 22 episodes a season. You know, it’s going to be 13 or 22 hours.
0:28:28 Video game, our average duration of gameplay that includes games like Candy Crush is an hour per
0:28:36 person per day. Games like Call of Duty or World of Warcraft are hours a day. So the interest in
0:28:41 the engagement and the commitment that you’re making to that form of media is so different
0:28:50 than film and television. In my view, you have the right to have a strong opinion and voice your
0:28:56 opinion in exchange for making that hour plus commitment a day, which becomes more of a lifestyle.
0:29:02 And so instead, you know, I think some companies run and hide and don’t really engage their user
0:29:08 base. But I think we have users and players who will and audience members who will tell you
0:29:14 and give you really good insight into how you can modify and adapt your game. So you listen to
0:29:20 them and they’re not always right. But oftentimes they’re pretty and especially when you hear the
0:29:27 sort of the mass view, they’re pretty right. The beauty of our business though is that if you
0:29:31 can get out in front of it early, let people actually have an experience with the game,
0:29:36 get the feedback and you’re willing to take that feedback and enhance and improve and modify the
0:29:40 games. It’s a great roadmap for innovation. So I’d like to ask you about two games that I think
0:29:44 are arguably transformative from a conceptual standpoint for gaming. And you tell me what
0:29:48 you think or maybe describe what you think are the structural significance of each of these.
0:29:52 And so the first is Fortnite. And you alluded to one of the dramatic changes. So maybe describe
0:29:57 like what is the significance of Fortnite to the industry? So for starters, there’s this perception
0:30:02 that Fortnite is an overnight success. It’s not epic. The company that made it has been in the
0:30:07 video game. Tim has been in the game business almost as long as I have been. And they are excellent
0:30:15 at making games. And what they did was to really spend the time in a very focused, determined way
0:30:20 taking the Unreal Engine and turning it to something that was going to be a broad appeal,
0:30:25 very compelling social experience. And I think the aspiration was build the social network that’s
0:30:32 anchored in a game conceit. And they made it cross-platform in its playability. They made it
0:30:39 very accessible. They changed the way that they deliver content to season. So moved from the
0:30:45 feature film model to the serialized television model. And it’s really fun. And they managed to
0:30:52 do what you probably can’t do intentionally, but capture the popular cultural zeitgeist.
0:30:58 And the other thing is that it doesn’t require you to make a two hour a day investment. You know,
0:31:04 you can have a 20 minute experience that is really satisfying. But this is not accidental. You know,
0:31:08 these guys have been doing this for a very long time. And I think what it has started to do is
0:31:14 broaden the appeal of games to people who might never have played games before.
0:31:17 And then what is the significance of Pokemon Go? And by the way, for people who don’t actually
0:31:21 just saw this yesterday, Pokemon Go, third party report. But the report was revenue last month was
0:31:26 still in the order of $75 million. So it’s still something like a billion dollar a year revenue
0:31:30 business today. And this is where the game is now what, two years old or something like that.
0:31:31 Almost three years.
0:31:34 At least rumor has it that they have new stuff coming. But it’s been a giant hit.
0:31:38 Again, it’s like, where’s the innovation there? But it’s like, you know,
0:31:44 Nintendo is really great at innovations that are very physical in their nature. So the Wii,
0:31:50 that moment I was describing to you about the Macintosh, when I first saw the prototype of the
0:31:57 Wii, it was like that equivalent goose bump moment. I was in Kyoto and I went into his room
0:32:04 and there was a TV and it wasn’t like an LED. It was an actual tube TV. And there was a pond that
0:32:10 was on the screen, like a little cartoon pond with little bubbles popping up from every once in a
0:32:15 while. And the head of Nintendo at the time was a guy named Iwata-san. And he gave me the controller.
0:32:19 And I held the controller and I just started going like this. And all of a sudden you could feel
0:32:26 the tension of the controller and the motion control of the controller. And I started to like
0:32:31 fish around and I grabbed the fish and I pulled the fish out. And I thought that video games
0:32:38 will be completely transformed. Nothing had really taken the physical experience in video games to
0:32:45 that level. And I think that what Pokemon Go did is something very similar. But it created this
0:32:52 physical experience that I think it was the first time AR had been executed on a broad scale.
0:32:59 And so I haven’t seen anything in gaming that I would tell you has really captured the imagination
0:33:06 of people on a broad scale using AR besides Pokemon Go. But I would say when you look at
0:33:09 where some of the next big innovations in gaming, including what we’re working on,
0:33:15 AR is going to have more near-term impact than VR. Amazing. Okay, good. And then final closing
0:33:19 question. What’s the one Activision game that has come out this year that people really have to
0:33:24 play? And then I know it may pain you, but I’m going to ask you, what’s the best non-activision game
0:33:29 that has come out this year that people really have to play? So I would say Call of Duty Blackhouse
0:33:35 4, which we just released, the blackout mode of Call of Duty Blackhouse 4 is so incredibly fun to
0:33:40 play. And what is that? What is that mode? It’s like a PUBG mode. It’s like a battle royale mode.
0:33:47 And it’s super fun to play. And you can do it in like small 25 minute increments, but very accessible,
0:33:53 very fun to play. I haven’t played Red Dead Redemption yet, but I want to. And I would say of the things
0:33:59 that have come out this year, I think it looks like Westerns are very hard to do because they’re
0:34:04 very American in their field. But the game looks fantastic. And everybody they know has played
0:34:08 it. Is that a lot of fun playing it? Yeah, fantastic. And I think we have party favorites. We brought
0:34:11 Call of Duty for everybody. Call of Duty. So I believe everybody’s going to have a copy of Call of
0:34:18 Duty. Bobby, thank you so much. Mark, thank you very much.
Bobby Kotick is the CEO of Activision Blizzard (a merger he engineered); it’s one of only two video gaming companies in the Fortune 500, and the largest game network in the world. The company is responsible for some of the most iconic entertainment franchises, including Call of Duty, Candy Crush, Overwatch, and World of Warcraft — as well as its own professional esports league.
So in this episode of the a16z Podcast, Marc Andreessen interviews Kotick on everything from the evolution of video games in the 1980s to gaming trends more broadly. What changes as gaming goes from ”just for nerds” to ”just for kids” and spreads more broadly into entertainment and cultural phenomena (esports, Fortnite, Pokemon Go, etc.)… both online and offline?
The conversation originally took place at our annual innovation a16z Summit in November 2018 — which features a16z speakers and invited experts from various organizations discussing innovation at companies small and large. You can also see other podcasts and videos from this event here: https://a16z.com/tag/summit-2018/
-
a16z Podcast: Who’s Down with CPG, DTC? (And Micro-Brands Too?)
AI transcript
0:00:06 Hi everyone, welcome to the A6NZ Podcast. I’m Sonal. Today is part of our ongoing series
0:00:12 on consumer tech trends. We’re talking all about the category of consumer packaged goods
0:00:18 or CPG and where this fits with what’s going on in online and offline commerce trends overall,
0:00:23 including when it comes to the grocery business. We also talk about the trends of DTC or direct
0:00:29 to consumer and the concept of micro or emerging brands as well. Joining us to have this conversation,
0:00:34 we have A6NZ General Partner Jeff Jordan, who’s written a lot about competing with Amazon and
0:00:38 the future of e-commerce and marketplaces and has been on the front lines of this area both as
0:00:43 an operator and investor, witnessing firsthand from many angles a lot of changes in the industry.
0:00:48 And then we also have Ryan Kahlbeck of Circle Lab, an investment platform powered by data and
0:00:53 technology. He also talks a lot about innovation in the CPG space and more, which is why we
0:00:58 invited him to join this discussion. Please note that the content here is for informational purposes
0:01:03 only should not be taken as legal business tax or investment advice or be used to evaluate
0:01:09 any investment or security. It’s not directed at any investors or potential investors in any fund.
0:01:15 For more details, please also see A6NZ.com/disclosures. The broader question that we covered throughout
0:01:21 this episode is how does technology and especially the internet change and in some ways not change
0:01:26 the way we do things. Why do some of the traditional businesses in these industries, though full of
0:01:32 some of the smartest people, have trouble innovating and can tech really help? In fact, that’s where
0:01:37 we begin the conversation with the assertion that it’s been hard to bring tech to CPG, even though
0:01:45 there seem to be a lot of products trying out there. As a user, I have a hard time perceiving this
0:01:50 because I am constantly bombarded with consumer products that are techie, whether it’s like
0:01:54 a thousand beauty product lines, there’s a thousand even generics lines that I’m getting hit with.
0:01:58 So I have a hard time grokking that this is a reality. Tell me what’s happening there.
0:02:05 It’s a great point. So I think, first, one of the reasons that you see that is the D2C movement,
0:02:11 which is direct to consumers. A handful of tech VC firms, they’re putting a fair amount of money
0:02:17 into consumer product companies that sell just direct to consumer or predominantly direct to
0:02:23 consumer. That money is usually not used for innovation, for product innovation. It’s usually
0:02:28 used for marketing. I agree with Ryan that they’re largely marketing companies. It’s actually
0:02:32 derivative of Amazon, unfortunately. If you want to play any e-commerce in a post-Amazon
0:02:37 era, you cannot sell what Amazon sells successfully. I mean, early on, we tried a number of concepts
0:02:43 that some are around anymore that said, okay, I can kind of sell the same thing as Amazon with
0:02:47 a different distribution twist with something like this, but you can’t. So then the next wave
0:02:52 of companies was, okay, if I can’t sell, I can’t compete with Amazon directly skew by skew,
0:02:58 let me get proprietary skews. And so they’re formulating different products with different
0:03:05 branding, and they typically aren’t on Amazon or on other retail. But that is where a lot of the
0:03:11 direct to consumer stuff is happening. And frankly, some success, not a ton of success
0:03:14 in doing it. Why is that, by the way? At some point, you’re still competing with
0:03:21 legacy players. And what’s worse is they’re also competing with each other. So there are a half
0:03:29 dozen, a dozen brands all trying to find you. Early on, they find you at $20 acquisition cost
0:03:34 when 10 of them go at each other. They’re competing for you, 10 companies trying to grow,
0:03:39 competing for you. And then that also caps their ability to price. So one of the big
0:03:44 secrets in e-commerce is virtually no companies get big and make money in the United States on
0:03:51 e-commerce. I can name five e-commerce companies in the US after two decades of investing and
0:03:56 God knows how many tens of billions of dollars who are a billion dollars in sales and profitable.
0:04:01 Yeah, I mean, you’re making the point, particularly around the rise in CAC. We see a lot of
0:04:07 DTC companies raise money with a CAC, let’s call it $10, $30. And then over the course of
0:04:13 subsequent two years, it raises literally sometimes by an order of magnitude. And that is just killing
0:04:17 their profitability. And by that, just to quickly summarize, you mean CAC is on customer acquisition
0:04:20 costs and they’re using all that marketing dollars to acquire their customers.
0:04:26 Exactly. I think when DTC directed consumer businesses, I think a lot of folks look at it
0:04:31 from the outside and say, okay, we’re stripping out the middleman, the retailer, the offline
0:04:36 retailer. And because of that, we can put that margin that the retailer gets into our business.
0:04:40 And this is going to be a wonderful business. The problem is that you need to attract people to
0:04:47 your site, right? To get people to come to your startup, to come to your URL and buy something
0:04:51 is a really difficult thing. And so that’s what’s driving these customer acquisition costs up.
0:04:55 Now, there are some DTC companies, Native Deodorant was bought. They only raised
0:04:59 two or three million bucks in total, sold for $100 million to Unilever.
0:05:03 Why did Unilever want to buy that company? Why wouldn’t they just make their own in-house brand,
0:05:09 another brand? The CPG companies, large ones, have lost the ability to innovate. They innovate
0:05:13 through acquisition now and they buy early. So Unilever bought Dollar Shave Club. Unilever
0:05:18 doesn’t have a shaving business. I don’t know Unilever Deodorant offerings, but I’m guessing
0:05:24 they saw something in there. So it and Biotech are kind of the same. The big pharma companies are
0:05:28 buying their innovation. The big CPG companies are buying their innovation. Historically,
0:05:34 large CPG has been able to rely on their brands. Brands that have existed literally in some cases
0:05:40 for 50 or 100 years. Meg, Scott Cook, and Brian, Sweetie, and Steve Ballmer, we’re all at P&G
0:05:45 together. Right after I graduated from college, Meg was the brand manager, I believe, on Crest.
0:05:52 Wow. That’s awesome. But can you think of that cadre of talent in all analysts in Cincinnati?
0:05:56 CPG seems like, because I have a lot of friends that go through their career starting at Clorox.
0:05:59 And it seems like sort of a training, there’s always like a mafia and a training ground that
0:06:02 people get some fundamental skills in these companies. So what are they actually getting
0:06:06 out of these companies? There’s a quote in one of the Apple movies, if you can sell sugar water,
0:06:12 you can certainly sell. That was Steve John’s quote, like he tried recruiting John Scully.
0:06:16 I think there’s probably something to that, right? To be able to sell literally the same product
0:06:19 for 30 years in a row. Think about trying to do that in the technology space. That’d be
0:06:26 impossible. There’s a fun book by a Harvard dean called Different. And it basically says,
0:06:31 almost all consumer goods are these small incremental improvements that everyone copies
0:06:38 because that’s the improvement that wider mouths on the Crest toothpaste because that you go through
0:06:44 it faster. Oh, so Colgate will do wider mouths and Spearman and whitening and versus brands that
0:06:50 kind of just throw it out and just do it differently. She uses Harley. She uses Apple. She uses Red Bull.
0:06:56 And they just came to market with completely, we are going to be different. And it’s so interesting.
0:07:02 I love the book because 99% is exactly the same. And then the 1% is different.
0:07:05 That gets back to the point of like why these large brands are losing market share.
0:07:11 The large brands have not had to innovate. They’ve been able to rely on their brands on,
0:07:16 whether it’s Coke or Pepsi or whatever it is, the same product, just their brand name for decades.
0:07:22 Now these smaller upstart brands, these emerging brands are able to develop the innovation in
0:07:27 house and deliver that to the consumer. The consumer, on the other hand, for the first time
0:07:32 in history is saying, I demand products that meet my unique needs. Maybe the three of us used to
0:07:37 eat the same breakfast cereal. Now the three of us are eating different things. We’re demanding
0:07:43 products that meet our unique needs. That customer consumer demand is pulling forward the innovation
0:07:46 and giving it a market. That’s why though, I just want to push a little bit more on this DTC topic
0:07:51 though, because when I think of the theory of the internet, which, you know, it disintermediates this
0:07:56 intermediary, you can go direct to people, you create movements on the internet. I mean,
0:08:00 talk about meme culture. Like if a meme can monetize, why the hell can’t a product?
0:08:03 So I’m still having a hard time buying why DTC is so hard.
0:08:07 The internet enables a long tail. So all of a sudden everything’s discoverable,
0:08:11 where it used to be, there were three television networks and 10 magazines that mattered.
0:08:18 The world is different. It used to have, you know, very narrow portals to work, which was great for
0:08:25 big companies that have stable product lines. So you couldn’t do TV on a $5 million revenue line.
0:08:29 You can do internet on a $5 million revenue line. Right. But that’s exactly my point,
0:08:33 is we have a world where we do have a long tail discoverability. You have the ability to access,
0:08:38 find your niche audience. You also have a world where you can still make hits on that long tail.
0:08:42 So you just describe why there’s a proliferation of CPG companies.
0:08:45 But why does DTC not work? That’s a part I don’t get.
0:08:49 When we say it doesn’t work, I think it is an incredible channel for iterating on a product.
0:08:54 I think it drives innovation. I can find my consumer base and I can test a new product.
0:08:57 Next month, I can test a different product. That’s very different than the offline world,
0:09:00 where if I’m selling into Safeway or Whole Foods or Costco down the street,
0:09:05 it’s hard for me to switch the product out if it’s not working, to tweak a package, whatever it is.
0:09:09 People in the technology space take that kind of A/B testing for granted. In CPG, it’s much,
0:09:12 much harder because you literally… Because it’s physical product and offline space.
0:09:14 Yeah, you have atoms, you need to move, not just bits.
0:09:18 And so if you run a chain of stores, actually a couple of my… All the companies that are
0:09:23 getting challenged growing, continuing to grow DTC sales are turning to offline retail in different
0:09:27 forms. Every company I’ve worked with is trying to do that because incremental sales…
0:09:29 That’s actually rather counterintuitive.
0:09:33 It is. But the way store management work, I used to be CFO of the Disney store, is
0:09:40 you try products. Typically, you do two or four sets a year and you try products in a
0:09:44 significant subset of your stores because if it’s a bomb, you don’t want to buy
0:09:48 deep in it. So you’ll put it in five stores a test for the first six months.
0:09:52 And then they say, “That worked well. Let’s go to 50 stores for the next six months.”
0:09:56 And then by the time you get chain-wide, it literally is a couple of years later.
0:10:00 And so it’s really hard to grow your business.
0:10:03 And that’s for Disney stores where you have your own product in the store.
0:10:09 So if you think of the CPG products, they’re selling through a third party, the retailer.
0:10:14 Now, they have to make a much bigger bet. They can’t usually just start in five safe ways.
0:10:18 So they have to start in 200. Now when you start in 200, flipping that and changing that product,
0:10:21 if it didn’t work, it can kill the company.
0:10:26 When I was at Xerox PARC, one of the companies we partnered with was a large CPG company.
0:10:30 And their number one challenge was trying to figure out what happens after the consumer
0:10:33 buys the product. They had zero insights.
0:10:35 Oh, actually, it’s even worse. They have zero insight.
0:10:40 They know what they sell into the retail chains. They don’t know what’s sold where to who.
0:10:41 Right. Seriously?
0:10:41 No. It’s incredible.
0:10:42 It’s absolutely incredible.
0:10:44 That’s great. That’s crazy. How is that not possible?
0:10:47 So people who are listening to this will respond, “Well, what about credit card data?”
0:10:50 The problem with credit card data is it can tell you what the retailer is selling,
0:10:51 not what was bought at the retailer.
0:10:54 So I can see what Nordstrom.com sales for last month.
0:10:56 I can’t see what pairs of jeans were bought there.
0:10:58 Why not? Doesn’t it say?
0:10:58 They don’t sell.
0:11:00 Isn’t that the whole point of a skew?
0:11:03 No. Well, yeah, but these credit card companies don’t sell it.
0:11:08 And more importantly, back to Jeff’s point, they don’t tie those products to individual people.
0:11:16 Some retailers have loyalty card data, but there’s privacy issues with them selling that.
0:11:22 $84.51, a division of Kroger sells part of it, but not in the way that we’re talking about here.
0:11:26 They can say, “This person who I can, by the way, I can match Sonals,
0:11:29 what her purchasing power to your Instagram account, that is not done anywhere.”
0:11:33 Typically, CPG marketing is you buy a circular in the Sunday paper.
0:11:35 You buy an end cap, and you have no idea–
0:11:37 An end cap being the little display at the end of the grocery store.
0:11:38 At the end of the aisle in the grocery store.
0:11:42 And billions of dollars goes into those, and who knows if it works.
0:11:48 And they certainly don’t have any data beyond, “Oh, our total sales went up a little bit there.”
0:11:53 One of the key things that was compelling about Instacart to us is that they have a revenue
0:11:56 stream from the consumer, a revenue stream from the grocery retail partner,
0:12:00 and a revenue stream from CPG companies who are interested in accessing the consumer.
0:12:04 Why the CPG companies were so interested in that is,
0:12:06 it’s the first performance marketing they’ve ever seen.
0:12:09 On something like Instacart, they know everything I’ve ever bought.
0:12:15 And if they know I love Heineken beer and the product manager of Stella wants to try to convert me,
0:12:19 they can give me a Stella coupon, a Stella samples, a Stella, everything else.
0:12:21 And then see, did I change my behavior over time?
0:12:23 That’s the holy grail of marketing.
0:12:24 The holy grail for marketing.
0:12:26 I mean, performance marketing, like that type of data,
0:12:29 like closing that feedback loop is a big F-deal.
0:12:34 They also over time have the ability to kind of literally move the product on the page, right?
0:12:36 Which if you think about offline retail, you can’t do.
0:12:38 What do you mean by on the page?
0:12:43 Meaning when you’re looking at Instacart, what product you’re looking for can be moved physically.
0:12:47 Oh, like kind of personalized rearrange to your needs.
0:12:47 Exactly.
0:12:48 Which you cannot do in a physical way.
0:12:50 And it’s completely obvious in tech.
0:12:52 But for people that are in CPG, it’s a game changer.
0:12:57 So I was in a Safeway half a mile from here on Sand Hill six months ago,
0:12:59 and was buying some steak.
0:13:01 Steak was in the refrigerator.
0:13:04 Next to the steak in the refrigerator were wood chips.
0:13:06 The wood chips have no need to be refrigerated.
0:13:08 They’re literally just wood chips to put in a barbecue.
0:13:11 They’re in the refrigerator because they’re on sale.
0:13:13 And they want to put them next to the steak.
0:13:14 That’s it.
0:13:16 And so you’re refrigerating literally wood.
0:13:17 That’s crazy.
0:13:19 Because back to Jeff’s point, if I bought an end cap,
0:13:21 the end cap would have been 30 feet away.
0:13:23 Then you would have lost the consumers.
0:13:24 And they need to have that proximity.
0:13:26 That’s a crazy awesome example.
0:13:27 I love that.
0:13:30 Let’s talk about grocery for a little bit as an interesting category.
0:13:35 So first of all, is grocery going to go the way of malls and other retail?
0:13:37 So I’ve got a not very popular opinion on this.
0:13:38 Let’s hear it.
0:13:39 The more popular, the better.
0:13:43 I think grocery stores are here for the very, very long term.
0:13:46 Very long term, meaning next 20 years at least.
0:13:50 So taking a step back, D2C and e-commerce has been around for 20 plus years.
0:13:52 This is not a recent phenomenon.
0:13:55 Food is still, Jeff, you could tell me, I think 5% of sales.
0:13:56 Of digital?
0:13:56 Yeah.
0:13:57 Way under.
0:13:58 Yeah.
0:14:02 I don’t foresee a world in which everyone is just going to go online, A.
0:14:07 And B, when that happens or when it gets to be a much higher proportion of where you buy
0:14:13 your groceries, I still think that that grocery is going to be delivered locally.
0:14:18 But the core point is grocery today, 2%, 3% net margin business.
0:14:21 That’s hard to strip out a lot of costs from that.
0:14:21 There’s not a lot of room left to go.
0:14:23 You can’t do any cost cutting at all.
0:14:23 That’s right.
0:14:29 So you think about where technology has been particularly successful at killing other industries.
0:14:32 They tend to be industries where there’s a fair amount of profit, right?
0:14:35 It’s also like Bommel’s cost disease, too, if you think about it, eventually penetrating
0:14:39 health care and education, like things that are way more expensive than they need to be.
0:14:41 And technology is a vector to just cut right through that.
0:14:42 Absolutely.
0:14:46 But the safety down the street has a 1.5% net margin.
0:14:48 So what are we going to do to rip the cost of that?
0:14:52 Because that thing is already delivering a pretty good product to the people that live within a
0:14:53 mile and a half of here.
0:14:57 I mean, there was a set of companies that was trying to help physical retail compete
0:14:58 with the digital commerce.
0:14:59 And it was so interesting.
0:15:04 We didn’t invest in many of them at all because our internal reference was we’re shorting the
0:15:05 future.
0:15:08 You know, just so it’s not a long-term winning proposition and their margins are going to
0:15:10 get squeezed, so they’re going to squeed their vendors.
0:15:13 Then we made the Instacart investment in the belief that the grocery stores are there.
0:15:15 It’s distributed.
0:15:17 They have distributed little warehouses.
0:15:18 They provide service.
0:15:19 And it was interesting.
0:15:22 Fred Smith, the founder of FedEx, when the internet first came up said,
0:15:26 “I think a whole lot of goods are going to be delivered by FedEx.
0:15:27 Groceries ain’t going to be one of them.”
0:15:32 Because the concept that you’re going to load a truck in the morning and having
0:15:36 bouncing down the streets and this and that and deliver at 8.
0:15:40 It’s something at 8 p.m. that was put in the truck at 4.30 a.m.
0:15:42 And he just said, “I don’t think it works.”
0:15:47 Building up the shopper network is so hard to replicate for someone else going forward.
0:15:50 It’s not as simple as, “Let’s just hire FedEx to go do this thing.”
0:15:54 Oh, and the operational intensities observe.
0:15:58 We think in grocery, we think effectively there are a couple different dimensions
0:15:59 that grocery chains need to compete on.
0:16:01 We think it’s assortment.
0:16:03 We think it is convenience.
0:16:05 We think it is pricing and experience.
0:16:07 Pricing is a really, really hard place to compete on.
0:16:10 You’re competing with Amazon to a point that Jeff made earlier.
0:16:12 You’re competing with Walmart.
0:16:14 I think that’s just a really, really hard place to win.
0:16:15 Yeah, you can’t win on price.
0:16:18 Especially when you already have this 1% to 2% margin.
0:16:20 Exactly. The margins are already so low.
0:16:22 So let’s put pricing aside for a second.
0:16:28 I also think that grocery is, in some ways, an experience for some people.
0:16:33 An experience for the consumer to go in, perhaps with the family,
0:16:36 perhaps just buy a couple of things here and there.
0:16:38 They want the immediacy of that.
0:16:41 We don’t see that going away anytime soon.
0:16:43 I think it’s going to be hard to win, again,
0:16:47 because how do you invest into an experience if you have such low margins?
0:16:49 I will say one quick sidebar on experience,
0:16:50 such as if Connie were in this room,
0:16:52 she talks a lot about what happens in China.
0:16:55 And she talks about this incredibly fascinating phenomenon
0:16:59 where grocery stores in China have become destinations themselves
0:17:01 because there’s literally restaurants inside.
0:17:04 They’re doing all kinds of neat food chef things, etc.
0:17:06 Cooking on site, doing all these interesting things.
0:17:07 I mean, what should you take on that?
0:17:10 I was with the CEO of a large grocery chain about a month ago
0:17:12 who made that same point.
0:17:14 They are starting to experiment by putting restaurants,
0:17:18 effectively restaurants, inside their grocery chain.
0:17:22 The local Asian supermarkets almost all have restaurants forever.
0:17:23 Indian ones, too.
0:17:25 They have like samosas for $2.
0:17:25 Yeah.
0:17:30 I would say I think it is nice to have not a requirement to be successful.
0:17:33 I’m not convinced that that’s going to be the core differentiator going forward.
0:17:35 So what do you think is going to be the core differentiator?
0:17:35 You had one more dimension.
0:17:38 Well, convenience and assortment, those are the last two.
0:17:40 So convenience, to me, is delivery.
0:17:41 Delivery or in-store pickup.
0:17:45 I think that that will end up being table stakes, not a nice to have.
0:17:47 Meaning you need to have convenience.
0:17:50 Well, my question on this is why bother even having a grocery store
0:17:51 if you only need to deliver?
0:17:53 Why not keep warehouses then?
0:17:54 If experience isn’t going to win the thing.
0:17:56 Like why not just have a bunch of warehouses
0:17:57 that deliver food if delivery is the thing?
0:17:58 Yeah.
0:18:01 So to be frank, that could be the 50-year vision.
0:18:02 That really could.
0:18:04 In the UK, which for whatever cultural reason
0:18:06 has been doing grocery delivery for a long time
0:18:09 and it’s a much deeper state of penetration,
0:18:11 they’re starting to have what’s called dark stores,
0:18:14 where you basically, they look a lot like supermarkets.
0:18:16 They’re locally distributed.
0:18:17 They have inventory assortment,
0:18:19 but they’re not in high traffic parts of town,
0:18:22 which means the rents are much, much lower.
0:18:26 And so, as a result, you don’t have to make it pretty.
0:18:28 You don’t have to have the lights, lots of lights.
0:18:29 You don’t have to have high labor.
0:18:30 All you have to do is pick in them.
0:18:33 And so that is how grocery has been developing
0:18:36 in one of the most advanced digital grocery markets.
0:18:39 So it’ll be interesting if whether that happens in the US,
0:18:43 every argument that I can make on why grocery stores won’t
0:18:46 just be warehouses where it gets delivered from,
0:18:49 every argument that I can make is a short-term argument.
0:18:51 I can’t make a 50-year argument for that.
0:18:53 So I think that that could happen.
0:18:55 Over the next 10 years, I don’t think customer adoption
0:18:56 will be big enough to get rid of these stores.
0:18:59 These stores, these aren’t little mom and pops.
0:19:02 They’re Fortune 500 companies that would not go down
0:19:03 without a really big fight.
0:19:04 No, and I think there are destinations.
0:19:06 I mean, I see like families on the weekends all the time.
0:19:08 It’s like, it’s an outing to go to the grocery store,
0:19:10 which if they had like a daycare,
0:19:12 I think that would be a huge win, frankly.
0:19:14 That alone would be a big differentiator.
0:19:15 I would love that.
0:19:16 I know, I think everybody would take that.
0:19:18 I exclusively shop through Instagram.
0:19:20 I do our family’s grocery because I can’t bring the kids
0:19:23 to the grocery store because it’s too much of a disaster.
0:19:26 So I believe that convenience will be table stakes.
0:19:29 So then it comes down to what is the way grocery wins?
0:19:30 What are the way grocery store competes?
0:19:32 To me, it is just about assortment.
0:19:33 That’s your fourth dimension.
0:19:33 This is the fourth dimension.
0:19:36 After price, experience, convenience, and now assortment.
0:19:37 That’s right.
0:19:40 Assortment is what are the products that are on the shelf?
0:19:43 So if you think the last 80 years,
0:19:46 it has been, well, what’s Pepsi gonna give us this month?
0:19:49 Coke, General Mills, Unilever, Procter & Gamble, et cetera.
0:19:50 Today, as we’ve talked about,
0:19:53 consumers want brands and products to meet their unique needs.
0:19:57 The problem with that is that the buyer at the retailer,
0:20:00 meaning the person that selects, let’s say, the chocolate company,
0:20:03 the buyer at the retailer is still the same buyer
0:20:06 that lived there 20 years ago in some cases.
0:20:08 They don’t use a lot of data.
0:20:10 They’re literally trying chocolate bars
0:20:11 to decide what goes on the shelf.
0:20:13 That’s a really hard place to be in a market
0:20:16 that is trillions of dollars
0:20:19 to decide which of these emerging brands they want to work with.
0:20:23 So the default is, gosh, maybe I just rely on the big brands
0:20:24 to tell me who to work with.
0:20:25 That’s a real example.
0:20:27 Sometimes the big brands literally say,
0:20:29 work with these emerging brands.
0:20:30 Maybe I work with the distributor,
0:20:33 who, by the way, has paid more than by the larger brands.
0:20:35 But there isn’t really a good solution
0:20:38 for a lot of these Fortune 500 retailers
0:20:41 on how to optimize their assortment.
0:20:45 The data that exists for these grocery chains is pretty poor.
0:20:48 You’ve got a couple retail-level sales providers
0:20:51 that on average track 20,000, 30,000 products,
0:20:53 or companies, rather, each.
0:20:56 There’s about a million and a half out there.
0:20:58 A million and a half, and they cover less than 5% of them.
0:21:00 And even the grocery and food shows, aren’t they?
0:21:03 Sort of like, I’m thinking of the equivalent in fashion
0:21:03 and boutiques.
0:21:05 You essentially have a fashion show
0:21:07 to curate all the brands, the emerging brands,
0:21:09 the existing brands, new product lines.
0:21:11 Why isn’t there an anthropology of grocery stores?
0:21:13 Because when I think of anthropology as a retailer,
0:21:16 they have assortment because they go around the world
0:21:17 to find a variety of designs.
0:21:20 So it works very well for a certain demographic of women,
0:21:22 like in their 20s, 30s, et cetera.
0:21:25 Then you have to say, which of these will my consumers
0:21:27 respond to at the rate price?
0:21:29 So you get exposed to the million,
0:21:33 but then I can only carry X,000 in my store.
0:21:34 How do I figure that out?
0:21:36 Online might actually help,
0:21:38 because you can put infinite selection online
0:21:39 and see what’s selling.
0:21:42 So if you’re a grocer, I’d be looking at my online sales
0:21:44 just to inform my offline sales.
0:21:46 Like, oh, wow, that’s a breakout hit online.
0:21:48 Why wouldn’t it be a breakout hit offline?
0:21:51 Interestingly, then, you might come back to a customer
0:21:53 acquisition challenge for the CPG companies,
0:21:56 which is if we have a ton of products online,
0:21:57 how do we then stand out?
0:21:59 That comes back into advertising.
0:22:00 This kind of vicious circle.
0:22:01 Or virtuous.
0:22:02 Or virtuous.
0:22:03 It’s a skewed sample, too.
0:22:05 Like what happens online and offline sometimes.
0:22:05 It’s definitely skewed.
0:22:08 But if you’re in a complete information vacuum,
0:22:09 which essentially these guys are, at least you have something.
0:22:11 Even, by the way, loyalty cards are a really skewed sample.
0:22:14 That’s a very self-selected, self-interested group.
0:22:16 You’re not really getting the huge untapped space
0:22:16 of what people want.
0:22:19 You’re not, but you’re actually finally getting data
0:22:21 on a per person basis to kind of understand what’s there.
0:22:22 Exactly.
0:22:26 It’s hard to understate how blind most buyers
0:22:29 at most physical retailers are right now.
0:22:31 Yeah, they’re just kind of, it’s instinct.
0:22:33 It’s, you optimize the current assortment.
0:22:36 But then how do you layer in new things is,
0:22:38 and there’s a plethora of new things.
0:22:39 Or just everything that you don’t know
0:22:41 people have the taste for.
0:22:41 Exactly.
0:22:42 So you think about that you’ve got a buyer
0:22:44 for the chocolate category, right?
0:22:47 And that could be an older, candidly white male
0:22:49 who’s making a decision on the entire category.
0:22:50 For a very diverse audience.
0:22:53 By the way, not diverse racially by age,
0:22:57 a certain gender, demographic, location.
0:22:59 So should we be selling the same thing in LA
0:23:00 that we do in Vermont?
0:23:02 So how are people going to get this data?
0:23:03 Because right now Jeff is describing
0:23:04 that they’re desperate for data.
0:23:06 So they have to rely on these,
0:23:07 they have to get data somewhere.
0:23:09 But that’s still adverse selection type data.
0:23:11 It’s not like the true opportunity space of data.
0:23:12 So where does the data come?
0:23:15 Broadly speaking, in consumer,
0:23:16 there’s a really beautiful thing
0:23:17 that a lot of people that don’t live and breathe
0:23:19 this space, they don’t recognize,
0:23:21 which is there is a tremendous amount of data
0:23:22 that’s out there in the world.
0:23:26 Meaning I can already see where a product is sold,
0:23:28 how many SKUs a company has,
0:23:30 meaning how many products that company sells,
0:23:32 what the price points of the products are,
0:23:33 what the end users think of the product.
0:23:34 And if I’m tracking it,
0:23:37 I can see how all those things change every single month
0:23:39 and how they compare to every other company in the category.
0:23:43 Those factors have been shown to be predictive of success.
0:23:46 People can aggregate those.
0:23:47 Now the challenge,
0:23:48 and this is where it gets really tricky.
0:23:51 The challenge is that you’re consolidating information
0:23:53 across literally hundreds of unstructured data sources.
0:23:55 It’s extremely intensive,
0:23:57 extremely intense and very difficult.
0:23:59 Sounds like a deal for an AI solution.
0:23:59 Yeah, it is.
0:24:00 It is.
0:24:01 But the data is out there is my point.
0:24:05 We think that that data is going to start getting consolidated
0:24:08 by data providers, technology companies,
0:24:11 that then sell it to the CBG companies,
0:24:13 or in this case, the grocery chains.
0:24:15 So the data opportunity, do you believe that?
0:24:15 Yeah, no.
0:24:17 We actually have seen a ton of companies trying to do it.
0:24:23 The interesting part is how hard they have to work to get the data.
0:24:24 There have been a whole bunch of them
0:24:28 that are trying to incent consumers to take pictures of their receipts
0:24:29 and submit the pictures.
0:24:32 And they do Optical Character Direct Edition on the picture
0:24:34 to try to reverse engineer.
0:24:36 What did Jeff buy?
0:24:37 We’ve seen multiple companies trying to do that.
0:24:39 There are other approaches too.
0:24:42 There was an on-demand,
0:24:45 they’d send armies of people with smartphones
0:24:46 to take pictures of shelves
0:24:48 so that they know the competitive pricing.
0:24:53 Oh, look, Crest is $2.29 and Colgate is $3.15.
0:24:54 What happened to sales?
0:24:57 But they don’t know what Colgate and Crest is,
0:24:58 and so they don’t know.
0:25:03 All they know is my philosophy in the southern region slowed down.
0:25:04 Or it’s sped up and you don’t know why,
0:25:05 which is equally problematic actually.
0:25:07 In the case of the receipts companies,
0:25:08 we’ve seen a lot of those too.
0:25:10 The challenge has been many of them tap out
0:25:13 at five, 10 million consumers, at least here in the US.
0:25:16 The problem with that level is that then,
0:25:18 that’s such a small portion of the overall population
0:25:21 that you’re not capturing the long tail of companies.
0:25:25 The chances that the $5 million popcorn company
0:25:29 is bought in a population that small is relatively low.
0:25:30 They’re going to be buying
0:25:31 the Procter & Gamble’s General Mills of the world,
0:25:33 but then you’re just getting more data
0:25:34 on the larger companies.
0:25:35 They need it on the smaller ones.
0:25:37 Exactly, they need data on the long tail.
0:25:40 Okay, so in this world, this long tail world,
0:25:42 this world of offline and online distribution,
0:25:44 and those are the two distribution broadly
0:25:45 that we’re talking about.
0:25:47 We are seeing a lot of microbrands,
0:25:48 and we didn’t talk about that
0:25:50 when we were talking about direct-to-consumer.
0:25:51 I mean, there’s a whole lot of media pieces
0:25:53 dissecting this phenomenon.
0:25:54 First of all, what is a microbrand
0:25:57 and why does it matter, or is it just a hypey thing?
0:25:59 Yeah, so let me just clarify.
0:26:02 By microbrand, you mean an emerging consumer product company
0:26:05 typically called less than $10 or $15 million in revenue.
0:26:08 So yes, but I think you’re the one who argues
0:26:10 that it denotes size, not channel,
0:26:12 because the way I’ve read it in the media,
0:26:13 it does talk about it as well.
0:26:15 Yeah, so the recent Economist article
0:26:16 kind of confused the two.
0:26:17 They started talking about microbrands,
0:26:19 and then they said, basically implied
0:26:21 that microbrands means D to C.
0:26:24 Micro to me, unless I’m missing something,
0:26:26 denotes size, not channel.
0:26:28 So I don’t really love that term to be candid with you.
0:26:29 Why didn’t you like it?
0:26:30 Well, for the same reason,
0:26:32 I would imagine that the entrepreneurs around here
0:26:35 wouldn’t like it if we called them micro technology companies.
0:26:36 They’re starting companies
0:26:37 because they want to build something big.
0:26:41 And I think that sometimes that comes across
0:26:43 as a little bit high and mighty, perhaps,
0:26:46 but especially if it’s just an ice cream company.
0:26:47 But look, I’ll be frank with you.
0:26:51 The ice cream company that’s able to strip out
0:26:53 fat and calories from the ice cream
0:26:54 and still deliver great products,
0:26:56 to me, is having a bigger impact on the world.
0:26:57 This is like Halo, right?
0:26:59 Halo Top, yeah, it’s exactly right.
0:27:03 So when we talk about them as emerging brands,
0:27:07 so emerging brands can be sold certainly offline or online.
0:27:09 But what’s happening,
0:27:12 these brands are growing very, very quickly right now.
0:27:14 In every single category in consumer,
0:27:17 large brands are losing share to emerging brands.
0:27:19 And the large brands are just terrified by this.
0:27:20 So why is it happening?
0:27:22 We think three primary reasons.
0:27:25 First is what we talked about
0:27:27 before the personalization of the consumer.
0:27:29 Consumers are demanding products that meet their unique needs.
0:27:31 Two other reasons that are pretty relevant
0:27:32 to this conversation.
0:27:36 One is decline in distribution costs.
0:27:39 Really, instead of just saying it’s a decline,
0:27:41 it’s really a shift from fixed costs
0:27:43 to variable costs.
0:27:44 And that’s because of the internet,
0:27:46 like the entry point to be able to buy,
0:27:47 get up a business up and running.
0:27:50 The internet is part of the driver,
0:27:52 but I don’t want to imply that that is the key driver.
0:27:55 In my view, it’s more that the offline retailers
0:27:58 are hungry to work with the small brands.
0:27:59 They’re struggling to figure out how to do it.
0:28:01 And so what we’re seeing is many of the offline retailers
0:28:04 are eliminating or lowering slotting fees.
0:28:07 Slotting fees are the cost to get your product on the shelf.
0:28:08 So if I want to launch a new chocolate bar
0:28:09 to get on the shelf of Safeway,
0:28:12 it is literally $50 to $100,000 just to get it on the shelf.
0:28:13 Think about that for a second.
0:28:15 If it’s the Apple App Store to launch an app,
0:28:18 it’s $100,000, it’d be a huge buried entry.
0:28:21 That fixed cost is declining rapidly
0:28:22 over the last five or 10 years.
0:28:23 Because these big brands are eager for–
0:28:25 The grocery stores are eager for these smaller brands.
0:28:27 More assortment, actually.
0:28:27 That’s right.
0:28:29 The third driver for why these emerging brands
0:28:32 have been so successful over the last five or 10 years
0:28:33 is marketing costs.
0:28:36 And that does get back to your point about the internet.
0:28:39 So marketing costs have also flipped from fixed to variable.
0:28:41 Fixed, meaning it used to be, let’s buy an ad in us weekly.
0:28:42 It cost me $100,000.
0:28:43 Or Jeff’s circular example.
0:28:44 Circular example is a great one.
0:28:47 Today, it is, let’s say, it’s the dollar-shaped flood YouTube ad.
0:28:50 And that’s an extreme example.
0:28:52 But you’re able to at least get your product out there
0:28:54 on a variable cost basis.
0:28:57 Because the flick fixed to variable transition,
0:29:00 these smaller brands, these emerging brands,
0:29:02 are able to grow much more effectively
0:29:03 than they could have 10 years ago.
0:29:05 So it literally is a variable cost.
0:29:07 When I was managing eBay, we were doing TV
0:29:09 and it was $1 million to produce an ad.
0:29:13 And then $10 million to distribute it with a frequency
0:29:15 that the brand people thought was efficient.
0:29:20 So $11 million was the ante to go on television for eBay at the time.
0:29:24 And so now you can go buy a $10,000 of Facebook ads
0:29:26 and try to reach your core audience.
0:29:28 So when you think about where this goes
0:29:30 in terms of innovation in the consumer space,
0:29:33 we think that over the next 10, 15, 20 years,
0:29:36 the brands that win, there will be more of them,
0:29:39 but they will get to a smaller level.
0:29:41 So what I mean is in the last 10 or 15 years,
0:29:44 the brands that won, Chabani, et cetera,
0:29:47 you can build multi-billion-dollar businesses.
0:29:51 I’m skeptical if that’s true in CPG going forward.
0:29:52 I mean, it’s almost math
0:29:56 because the total grocery market’s growing one or 2% a year.
0:29:58 If the number of brands proliferate,
0:30:00 the average revenue per brand should come down.
0:30:01 That’s exactly right.
0:30:04 But there’s no possibility for a player
0:30:08 like with Coke or Pepsi or white vitamin water or LaCroix.
0:30:10 So there’s certainly some very, very smart people
0:30:12 that disagree with me on this point.
0:30:17 I don’t see a world in which consumers want less options
0:30:19 where they’re saying, “Look, I want to go to the grocery store.
0:30:20 I want to go on Instacart.
0:30:22 And I only want to see one chocolate bar.
0:30:25 I don’t want to see something that’s different
0:30:27 for Sonal versus Ryan versus Jeff.
0:30:28 We don’t foresee that happening.”
0:30:31 Yeah, my view on that whole debate always comes down
0:30:34 to when people talk about more choice versus less choice.
0:30:36 Always comes down to actually what is the right choice for me.
0:30:38 And that does go to your point about personalization.
0:30:41 But the nuance I would say and data
0:30:42 is that it doesn’t necessarily have to do
0:30:43 with how many choices you have,
0:30:45 but that the right choices are presented to you.
0:30:45 Absolutely.
0:30:47 And that’s going to be a huge challenge.
0:30:49 Whoever the grocery chain or in this case,
0:30:50 or in the case of Instacart,
0:30:53 is to be able to present the right choices to you.
0:30:55 But we don’t think that the answer is going to be,
0:30:57 “Let’s strip out the choices altogether.”
0:30:57 Right.
0:31:01 And in 20 years ago, the choice was Coke or Pepsi.
0:31:03 But if now you go into the beverage aisle
0:31:06 and there’s things that I don’t even recognize where I am.
0:31:06 Right.
0:31:07 You know, just saying you’re just like–
0:31:08 I really don’t even understand
0:31:09 still why people love LaCroix so much.
0:31:12 It’s just like water with like a little hint of a taste.
0:31:12 I still don’t get it.
0:31:13 It is passion fruit.
0:31:16 I’m so confused over this.
0:31:17 Well, let’s talk about data then.
0:31:19 So we’ve been scooting around this topic of data for a while.
0:31:20 The biggest thing I’ve heard so far
0:31:23 as we talk about online to offline
0:31:25 is that in the offline world,
0:31:27 it has been nearly impossible to get the data we want.
0:31:29 On one hand, I’ve heard you say, Ryan,
0:31:31 that there are many data sources out there
0:31:32 that are really good proxies
0:31:34 and that we can do a lot.
0:31:36 But Jeff, you’ve also said that people are starved for data,
0:31:38 that things are missing.
0:31:40 So tell me what the status is in the world of CPG and data.
0:31:43 Like where are we right now really on where–
0:31:46 how far data– what data can do in this world?
0:31:47 Well, so I think both are true.
0:31:49 Both that there is a lot of data
0:31:51 and that people are starved for data.
0:31:54 And the bridge there is that while there is an outrageous amount
0:31:56 of data in this industry,
0:31:58 the data is very hard to pull together.
0:32:01 And in some cases, impossible.
0:32:04 It’s just impossible to actually go get it.
0:32:08 So the data that’s out there around distribution,
0:32:09 around product uniqueness,
0:32:11 how unique a product is relative to its competitive set,
0:32:14 on what the user thinks of the product,
0:32:17 on the competitive set of that product, et cetera,
0:32:19 all that data is out there in the world.
0:32:20 And if you begin to kind of think about
0:32:22 where would I get that data?
0:32:24 Well, most brands are not trying to hide.
0:32:26 There’s no concept of living in stealth in consumers.
0:32:29 Yeah, you can’t really, like, hide your toothpaste.
0:32:32 That’s right. When I launch in my chocolate bar in the Whole Foods,
0:32:34 Whole Foods wants you to know that you can buy the Whole Foods,
0:32:36 and I want you to know you can buy the Whole Foods.
0:32:39 Similarly, I want you to know what’s in the product.
0:32:40 How you have an ingredient deck and nutritional panel
0:32:43 that’s mandated by the FDA, but it’s out there.
0:32:46 Then consumers talk about my chocolate bar.
0:32:47 That’s also key.
0:32:50 So people can begin to understand what people think of it.
0:32:53 They get the sentiment analysis of the data of the chocolate bar.
0:32:55 So if you think about, you know,
0:32:58 rewind to the first year slack was in existence, right?
0:33:00 So if you could see every customer that used slack,
0:33:03 what they paid for it, what the end users thought of the product,
0:33:05 and how all of those things changed every single month,
0:33:08 that’d be pretty valuable data for a lot of people to have.
0:33:12 You have that data on every single CPG company in existence.
0:33:13 It’s out there.
0:33:13 Who has it?
0:33:15 Well, that’s the challenge, right?
0:33:19 So the challenge is basically it’s out there living somewhere on Google.
0:33:22 Meaning if you Google the smallest brand you can find,
0:33:24 you can see everything that I just said.
0:33:29 The challenge, though, is how do you pull all that unstructured data together
0:33:30 and then normalize it?
0:33:32 So I see a brand on Amazon.
0:33:36 I see the same brand being sold and Whole Foods being talked about on Instagram, etc.
0:33:39 So a process that we call entity resolution.
0:33:42 I remember this from NLP where you have to essentially find the same entity
0:33:43 with different variations or names on it,
0:33:46 but be able to resolve that it is the same entity.
0:33:47 It’s an incredibly hard problem.
0:33:49 Right. It’s a lot harder than people think.
0:33:50 Yeah. And then on top of that,
0:33:55 you also have the problem of how do you know that that product is a chocolate bar
0:33:56 and not a pair of shoes?
0:33:57 That sounds like an easy problem.
0:34:00 I have eaten chocolate bars that taste like a bar of shoes.
0:34:03 You’re right. Chocolate bars do taste like shoes.
0:34:04 Not that I’ve actually eaten shoes.
0:34:06 I mean, have you eaten shoes?
0:34:07 You’re a basketball player.
0:34:08 I always put my foot in my mouth.
0:34:11 So that’s another challenge.
0:34:13 Is that now you think about the people that want to consume this data.
0:34:20 Grocery chains, large CPG companies, they’re not equipped to pull all that data
0:34:24 and structure data in, normalize it, make sense of it, match it together.
0:34:25 That’s not a core competency for them.
0:34:29 That’s why I strongly believe it’ll be a technology company that does that
0:34:31 and then sells that data to others.
0:34:34 Right. So that’s where you believe that CPG companies can compete
0:34:38 and where technology has a place to play by providing that data.
0:34:43 There is a ton of data, and yet people are running blind.
0:34:47 It’s not the data they need.
0:34:52 There’s data around. It’s not helping to make the important decisions
0:34:53 that are moving the needle.
0:34:56 In some cases, it’s not the data that they need.
0:34:58 In other cases, they’re not equipped to digest the data.
0:35:03 And you think of, okay, so at the grocery store, the chocolate buyer,
0:35:07 going back to that example, that’s trying to pick what chocolate bars are on their shelves,
0:35:11 they are used to, for their entire career,
0:35:14 basing it off of either A, their own taste, literally.
0:35:17 That’s how they try product or that’s how they decide products.
0:35:20 Or B, a small amount of retail-level sales,
0:35:23 bought from a very structured data source over and over again.
0:35:25 And that’s not competitive, right?
0:35:26 Because every company has access to that same data.
0:35:28 Every grocery store has access to that same data.
0:35:31 Everyone’s got this commoditized data.
0:35:32 Everyone’s using the exact same thing.
0:35:34 So now when you go to them and you say,
0:35:37 well, actually there’s this whole universe of data out there,
0:35:42 covers 30 to 50 times as many companies as your existing data source does.
0:35:42 Do you want to use it?
0:35:44 The answer is yes, but.
0:35:47 And the but is, well, how do I digest that?
0:35:51 I’m stuck in Excel, Windows 95.
0:35:53 That’s what I’m stuck using here.
0:35:55 How do I digest all of this data?
0:35:56 Who’s going to pull this together for me?
0:35:58 Because by the way, I’ve got literally one engineer
0:36:02 that works at the entire company, entire division that I’m in right now.
0:36:03 How am I going to do this?
0:36:05 That’s why we think it’s an outsource provider.
0:36:08 We think grocery stores and CBG companies
0:36:10 are either going to be buying it from a technology company
0:36:12 or they’ll have to buy that technology company,
0:36:13 bring it in-house.
0:36:16 It makes me think a little bit of automotive and traditional
0:36:19 Detroit car companies trying to become autonomous car companies.
0:36:22 And I think it’s fascinating because they could potentially
0:36:23 win on that front if the right competency is.
0:36:25 There are some really smart people in the grocery business.
0:36:26 Yeah, exactly.
0:36:27 Walmart’s diving in.
0:36:31 They’re also in top line sales right now in stores.
0:36:33 That said, it’s hard.
0:36:36 A lot of the best engineers might want to work for a grocery store
0:36:38 and might not want to live in Bentonville, Arkansas.
0:36:41 And then they’re incredibly low margin businesses.
0:36:44 So how do you hire a ton of really expensive engineers?
0:36:46 I give Walmart credit for making the bet.
0:36:47 They bought jet.
0:36:49 They bought a number of small–
0:36:50 They also have their own labs.
0:36:52 Like Walmart is known to be a little bit more innovative
0:36:54 with internal R&D than some of the other CBG players
0:36:55 that we’re talking about here.
0:36:58 But it’s not that the grocers aren’t capable
0:37:00 and don’t understand it.
0:37:02 They’re a bit of a prisoner’s dilemma.
0:37:05 There are extremely, extremely smart people working at both
0:37:08 large CBG companies and large grocery stores
0:37:10 that are in a really difficult position.
0:37:13 You think about what would you do if you were in their position?
0:37:14 Well, they’re out of business.
0:37:18 That’s, in the case of grocery, 2% net margin business.
0:37:20 How do they then say to their boss,
0:37:23 let’s go hire 150 engineers to go build this thing?
0:37:26 By the way, it’s not going to pay back for two or three years.
0:37:28 That’s a really, really hard proposition to make.
0:37:31 So I think incredibly talented smart people that work there,
0:37:33 it’s a hard position to be in.
0:37:35 One of the smartest people I’ve ever met in business
0:37:39 was the CEO of one of the largest consumer package companies.
0:37:42 And she came to Silicon Valley and wanted to sit down.
0:37:43 And I’m like, why are you here?
0:37:45 We believe software’s eating the world.
0:37:47 How is software eating snacks?
0:37:50 She came up with this very lucid argument of two things.
0:37:53 One is all of a sudden, there’s promotional transparency.
0:37:57 I used to move, gain share by going on special on knob,
0:38:00 Hills food one day and then special at Safeway.
0:38:02 Now the consumer knows exactly where I’m on special.
0:38:04 So I’ve lost the share moving thing,
0:38:08 all I’m doing is discounting and then nutritional transparency.
0:38:11 And so she says, I have to retool my company
0:38:15 because the two bedrocks that it was built on, software eight.
0:38:17 The challenge with that, and I, by the way,
0:38:19 I totally agree with that diagnosis.
0:38:22 The challenge then is that I don’t think that the CEOs
0:38:24 of these large CPG companies or large grocery chains
0:38:26 are given enough runway to go do that.
0:38:28 So there’s this, what we call 3G effect,
0:38:30 large financial institution down in South America
0:38:35 that has been investing into or buying public CPG companies,
0:38:36 basically stripping costs out.
0:38:39 And delivering shareholder value.
0:38:42 Problem with that is when you’re stripping the costs out,
0:38:44 one of the first things to go is R&D.
0:38:46 So you already had a problem for these large CPG companies.
0:38:48 What’s the percentage of R&D that they have?
0:38:51 So today, large CPG spends about 2% of sales in R&D.
0:38:52 Are you kidding?
0:38:55 Tech spends about 14% of sales in R&D.
0:38:57 CPG spends nothing on R&D.
0:39:01 And so- You have low margins, like 1.5 to 2% R&D.
0:39:01 That’s right.
0:39:03 So when you strip out costs,
0:39:06 I can deliver shareholder value and hit quarterly numbers
0:39:08 for the next, let’s say, year or two years.
0:39:10 But you look five, seven years out.
0:39:11 It’s not going to last long-term.
0:39:12 How far can you cut?
0:39:13 It’s like the activist investor problem, right?
0:39:14 That’s exactly right.
0:39:18 And so what we’re seeing is that many of these companies,
0:39:20 regardless of whether they’re doing that cost cutting or not,
0:39:23 they’re saying, look, we were already spending almost nothing on R&D.
0:39:24 How do we get the innovation?
0:39:26 And this goes back to a point Jeff made earlier.
0:39:27 That’s why CPG is beginning to look a lot
0:39:29 like Big Pharma has for the past 20 years.
0:39:31 So one last question then,
0:39:34 just to think about more on the data and innovation side.
0:39:36 All of us in this room are in the world of investing.
0:39:38 How does this change the investing game?
0:39:42 So in terms of how I think the investing landscape will change,
0:39:49 we have a pretty strong thesis that in CPG specifically,
0:39:52 there will be quantitative VC firms.
0:39:54 So what I mean by that is if you think of the public markets,
0:39:58 there are systematic quant funds that have historically,
0:40:00 over the last 20 years or so, in some cases 30 years,
0:40:05 invested into public companies basically just using technology.
0:40:07 It’s very different than a discretionary hedge fund
0:40:09 where you’ve got a team of really smart people
0:40:12 that research a stock for six months and make a decision.
0:40:14 In the case of a systematic quant fund,
0:40:17 they’ve got a lot of really, really smart engineers and data scientists
0:40:18 who are building algorithms to evaluate the company
0:40:20 and then make an investment decision.
0:40:23 We think that that is possible in some industries in the private markets.
0:40:26 We don’t think it’s possible in tech.
0:40:27 Why do you think that’s possible in CPG?
0:40:30 So there’s two main reasons that CPG is beautiful.
0:40:33 First, the business models are basically the same.
0:40:36 So what I mean is if I’m selling shampoo, dog food, or water,
0:40:37 the margins are different,
0:40:39 but I’m making a product and I’m selling the product.
0:40:40 It’s very different than tech.
0:40:42 In tech, I might give away the product for five years.
0:40:43 You might do a freemium, right?
0:40:44 I might do a SaaS business, et cetera.
0:40:45 Very different business models.
0:40:47 Because it’s the same business model,
0:40:49 it’s the same game of chess over and over again.
0:40:50 Interesting.
0:40:54 The second reason that there’s just an outrageous amount of data in this space,
0:40:59 but many of the dimensions that are predictive of success of a consumer company
0:41:01 are not data that you can get externally.
0:41:04 It’s hard to get information from afar.
0:41:05 In consumer, you can get it from afar
0:41:07 without ever talking to the company.
0:41:09 We have gone private financials on thousands of companies.
0:41:11 That acts as our training data.
0:41:13 The training data is private financials on thousands of companies.
0:41:15 And is that kind of providing the ground truth
0:41:16 in order to sort of compare the decisions again?
0:41:17 That’s exactly right.
0:41:18 Yeah, so it’s the ground truth.
0:41:23 So I need to know what success and failure looks like in order to predict it.
0:41:25 If you look at a SaaS company, a consumer company,
0:41:28 and an infrastructure company in tech, you can’t compare them.
0:41:31 Whereas if you’ve got two beverage companies,
0:41:38 and one is selling 20 units per Whole Foods per week at a 60% margin,
0:41:42 another selling 10 units per Whole Food per week at a 30% margin,
0:41:44 it’s pretty obvious which is the better company.
0:41:48 But also in CPG, I can find that company
0:41:50 just by using publicly available information.
0:41:52 So I can see that one of the two companies
0:41:55 started in one Whole Foods six months ago,
0:41:58 and now is in 400 Whole Foods and added 300 targets.
0:42:01 There isn’t really an equivalent in, let’s say, the SaaS world.
0:42:04 Going back to the SaaS world, while there might be structured metrics to look at,
0:42:06 and those metrics might be predictive of success,
0:42:08 almost all of them, not all, but almost all of them,
0:42:10 are only available once you start talking to the company
0:42:11 and you already know who to focus on.
0:42:14 I do wonder because when I watch a show like Billions,
0:42:16 you know, they have, they use data like empty parking lots
0:42:19 and aerial shots of an empty parking lot for retail
0:42:22 to be able to make a decision on whether to pull a trigger on a company or not.
0:42:24 The equivalent in SaaS might be developer heat,
0:42:28 like viral developer activity or the adoption rate among developers.
0:42:30 There’s various heat maps and sources.
0:42:32 The part that I have to ask on the big question
0:42:35 of quant investing in general, and especially in this case,
0:42:37 and even in our world, Jeff, which is more tech than CPG,
0:42:41 doesn’t it miss the outlier, the outsize winners?
0:42:42 It’s a great point.
0:42:43 It’s a great point.
0:42:43 Yeah.
0:42:46 So we, that’s another reason we struggle to believe
0:42:47 that it is possible in tech.
0:42:50 You think about many of the massive home runs in tech.
0:42:51 Exactly.
0:42:55 There weren’t prior examples that did something very similar.
0:42:56 No, they’re all, they’re all a priori.
0:42:57 Right. Yeah.
0:42:59 And so, so that’s why I really struggled to believe
0:43:00 that that’s possible in tech.
0:43:02 When you look at the winners and consumer,
0:43:04 the previous winners looked really similar.
0:43:06 That might have been a different,
0:43:07 might have been a different magnitude,
0:43:08 but they grew in really, really similar ways.
0:43:11 So this might be the one case where that phrase pattern recognition
0:43:13 that people throw around so wildly in the valley actually applies.
0:43:17 But who the winner was, wasn’t that still an irrational
0:43:20 behavioral thing versus something programmable?
0:43:24 So we’ve been able to show that there are some common themes
0:43:29 between both in A, why something wins and how it wins.
0:43:29 So here’s what I mean.
0:43:31 So you’re nuanceifying the two, which is really important.
0:43:31 That’s right.
0:43:36 So why typically the winners have, and look, to be clear,
0:43:37 this is not perfect.
0:43:39 There are holes, there are inaccuracies.
0:43:42 Typically the winners have brand intensity with the consumer.
0:43:44 So think of vitamin water 15 years ago,
0:43:49 kind bar 10 years ago, the brand really resonates with the consumer.
0:43:51 The second thing that is common amongst the winners in CPG
0:43:55 is the product has uniqueness that matters.
0:43:55 Interesting.
0:43:58 So kind bar is actually a pretty good example here.
0:43:59 When it first came out, everyone said,
0:44:00 “This is a really crowded category.”
0:44:03 By the way, everyone always says every CPG category is crowded.
0:44:06 Because they are, because they are, but they’re also massive.
0:44:08 Right, crowded but massive.
0:44:09 I like that distinction.
0:44:12 So kind bar, at the time though, what people missed was,
0:44:15 there’s Nature’s Valley, there’s Cliff Bar, a number of others.
0:44:18 When you look at those products, they didn’t look like real food.
0:44:21 Kind bar had an insight, which was,
0:44:23 “Let’s make a product that actually just looks like real food.”
0:44:24 That’s actually why I’m drawn to them.
0:44:26 I don’t feel like I’m eating a crappy processed bar.
0:44:28 Yep, and they actually show the food.
0:44:30 The biggest innovation for Guy Bar from my perspective is,
0:44:33 it’s see-through and you can see that there’s real food.
0:44:33 So you can see a whole lot to that.
0:44:35 And it’s not symmetrical.
0:44:35 Yeah, that’s exactly right.
0:44:36 Like it’s not this perfect rectangle.
0:44:38 It’s got like jagged edges where you can see it’s real.
0:44:39 It’s not processed.
0:44:41 Exactly, exactly, exactly.
0:44:45 So in that case, you know, you can build an algorithm
0:44:47 which evaluates the picture of the package.
0:44:49 And literally just says, “Is this different?”
0:44:51 So we’ve done that in the case of snack bars.
0:44:52 We track about 3,000 snack bars.
0:44:54 So you answer that question of, “Is it different?”
0:44:54 “Is it different?”
0:44:57 And then, now I could put fish in my snack bar
0:44:57 and it’d be different then,
0:44:59 but it may not resonate with the consumer.
0:44:59 Right, that would be great.
0:45:01 So those are two kind of orthogonal dimensions.
0:45:03 One is does it resonate with the consumer
0:45:05 and is the product unique?
0:45:08 The ones that have one tended to be high in both.
0:45:11 Then there’s the question of how it wins, right?
0:45:13 So why it wins and then how it wins.
0:45:16 The how it wins is typically distribution gains.
0:45:17 Distribution gains.
0:45:18 Meaning–
0:45:20 It’s because it’s not the one of Alex’s famous lines.
0:45:22 Like it’s always about distribution.
0:45:24 Yeah, yeah, it’s, and that is very true in CBG.
0:45:26 So there aren’t a lot of big winners
0:45:28 that have only been sold in five stores.
0:45:30 That’s not a thing.
0:45:31 So then if you think about,
0:45:34 okay, if it’s number of, it’s breadth and quality of doors,
0:45:35 meaning TG Max not as valuable
0:45:37 as let’s say Whole Foods or Costco.
0:45:40 So how do you measure breadth and quality?
0:45:41 That data is out there.
0:45:44 Where the product is being sold is out there in the world.
0:45:45 Whole Foods wants you to know it.
0:45:46 The brand wants you to know it.
0:45:48 Now it’s just aggregating that information
0:45:49 and making sense of it.
0:45:50 But that’s the how it wins.
0:45:52 And you can also get into price points.
0:45:53 You can get into skew count,
0:45:54 number of other things.
0:45:56 But marrying those two things together is the foundation.
0:45:58 But it’s basically one business model.
0:46:00 A couple of the differences in tech.
0:46:02 We’ve been trying to figure out,
0:46:04 how do you leverage data in the decision-making process?
0:46:05 Is this a holy grail?
0:46:09 Yes, we can probably define a dozen, two dozen,
0:46:12 three dozen different worlds of,
0:46:15 you know, universes of tech companies that are unique.
0:46:18 You have SaaS and open source and consumer.
0:46:20 And then within consumer, you have social and e-commerce.
0:46:23 So, you know, just by definition, comparison’s hard.
0:46:26 And then the other part you have is what you said,
0:46:28 most of the huge winners are lightning strikes.
0:46:30 Facebook was the second or third social network.
0:46:32 But, you know, no one was thinking social networks
0:46:35 when they talk about a trillion-dollar company.
0:46:40 eBay was collectibles online, weird, Facebook hot or not.
0:46:44 You know, these things, I mean, the Airbnb sleep on someone’s couch.
0:46:47 You know, these things don’t present as monster companies.
0:46:51 They start, hit a chord and are expanded
0:46:53 by their community of users.
0:46:54 And the thing I would add to that, by the way,
0:46:56 is that there’s a complexity math to this,
0:46:57 which is a little bit like the Brian Arthur,
0:46:59 we had Brian Arthur on the podcast.
0:47:00 And he’s the father of network effects
0:47:02 and network effects theory.
0:47:05 And the point of when that tipping point hits,
0:47:07 you don’t know when it tips.
0:47:07 That’s the hard one.
0:47:08 Yeah, yeah.
0:47:10 Like the when it seems like the really tough question.
0:47:11 Will it.
0:47:12 Then when, yeah, so it’s good.
0:47:14 And if you think of Jeff’s point,
0:47:15 like when Facebook hit,
0:47:17 there was two other social networks and maybe three.
0:47:17 Yeah.
0:47:19 There weren’t 300 or 3000.
0:47:20 Right.
0:47:21 There were very few examples.
0:47:24 You don’t have 40 or 400 examples
0:47:26 to begin to look at pattern recognition.
0:47:26 Right.
0:47:28 The n equals three or the CPG.
0:47:30 You’ve got massive data set.
0:47:33 So now I can compare certainly one ice cream company
0:47:34 to the many others that have hit.
0:47:36 But the difference between ice cream companies
0:47:37 and snack bars is not great enough
0:47:40 that you can’t compare the two and begin to see patterns.
0:47:42 Well, that was a fascinating discussion.
0:47:45 Ryan, Jeff, thank you for joining the ice cream company.
0:47:46 It’s a pleasure.
0:47:46 Thank you.
0:47:47 Thank you.
0:47:57 [BLANK_AUDIO]
with Ryan Caldbeck (@ryan_caldbeck), Jeff Jordan (@jeff_jordan), and Sonal Chokshi (@smc90)
It’s clear that all kinds of commerce companies and consumer products have been disrupted — or enabled — by tech. Yet for certain categories, like consumer packaged goods (CPG), it seems like tech hasn’t changed things very much. How is the rise of so-called ”micro-brands” (or emerging brands) playing out here?
And, how is it possible that ”real” — different — innovation isn’t really happening in the CPG industry, despite the tremendous legacy of brand, talent, and more in the space? How are CPG companies tackling grocery, which represents the perfect end-capsule and case study of challenges — and opportunities — in going from offline to online, from online to offline, and more? As for grocery itself, stores themselves (in the U.S. at least) haven’t changed very much due to tech, either… is it a last-mile delivery thing; could we also possibly move to distribution-only centers in the future?
Finally, while the holy grail of performance marketing and personalization remains elusive for the industry — let’s face it, most brands are still guessing in the dark (and forget trying to customize offerings!) — even going direct-to-consumer (DTC) hasn’t been shining as much of a light here as one might expect. Or so argue the guests in this episode of the a16z Podcast, featuring Ryan Caldbeck of CircleUp, along with a16z general general partner Jeff Jordan, in conversation with Sonal Chokshi. Cuz this episode is all about CPG, DTC; micro-brands, yah you know, all kinds of commerce.
-
a16z Podcast: To All the Robots I’ve Loved Before
AI transcript
0:00:02 Hi, and welcome to the A16Z podcast.
0:00:07 I’m Hannah, and this episode is a Valentine special where I talk with Kate Darling, researcher
0:00:12 at MIT Labs, all about our emotional relationships with robots.
0:00:16 We already know that we have an innate tendency to anthropomorphize robots, but as we begin
0:00:20 to share more and more spaces, both social and private, with these machines, what does
0:00:23 that actually mean for how we’ll interact with them?
0:00:28 From our lighter sides, from affection and love and emotional support to our darker sides,
0:00:33 what do these relationships teach us about ourselves, our tendencies, and our behaviors?
0:00:36 How will these relationships in turn change us?
0:00:40 And what models should we be thinking about as we develop these increasingly sophisticated
0:00:43 relationships with our robots?
0:00:47 Besides just that natural instinct that we have to anthropomorphize all sorts of things,
0:00:49 how is it different with robots?
0:00:54 Robots are just so fascinating because we know rationally that they’re machines, that
0:00:57 they’re not alive, but we treat them like living things.
0:01:04 With robots, I think they speak to our primal brain even more than a stuffed animal or some
0:01:10 other object that we might anthropomorphize because they combine movement and physicality
0:01:14 in this way that makes us automatically project intent onto them.
0:01:19 So that’s why we project more onto them than the Samsung monitor that I’m looking at back
0:01:23 here because it looks like it has agency in the world?
0:01:24 Yeah.
0:01:25 I think that tricks our brains.
0:01:28 There’s a lot of studies that show that we respond differently to something in our physical
0:01:31 space than just something on a screen.
0:01:35 So even though people will imbue everything with human-like qualities, robots take it
0:01:39 to a new level because of this physical movement.
0:01:44 People will do it even with very, very simple robots, just like the Roomba vacuum cleaner.
0:01:49 It’s not a very compelling anthropomorphic robot, and yet people will name them and feel
0:01:54 bad for them when they get stuck and insist on getting the same one back.
0:02:01 If it gets broken, and so if you take that and then you create something that is specifically
0:02:05 designed to push those buttons in us, then it gets really interesting.
0:02:10 So what is the reason why we should be aware of this tendency besides this cute attachment
0:02:15 to our Roombas or our vectors or whatever our pet robots are?
0:02:18 Why does it matter that we develop these relationships with them?
0:02:23 Well, I think it matters because right now, robots are really moving into these new shared
0:02:24 spaces.
0:02:30 I mean, we’ve had robots for decades, but they’ve been increasing efficiency in manufacturing
0:02:31 contexts.
0:02:34 They haven’t been sharing spaces with people.
0:02:39 And as we integrate these robots into these shared spaces, it’s really important to understand
0:02:43 that people treat them differently than other devices, and they don’t treat them like toasters.
0:02:49 They treat them subconsciously like living things, and that can lead to some almost comical
0:02:58 challenges as we try and figure out how to treat these things as tools in contexts where
0:03:03 they’re meant to be tools, but then at the same time kind of want to treat them differently.
0:03:08 When you talk about these giant manufacturing robots that do exist in plants and factories
0:03:11 on the floor, do we see that there?
0:03:17 So there’s this company in Japan that has this standard assembly line for manufacturing,
0:03:23 and a lot of companies, they have people working alongside the robots on the assembly line,
0:03:27 and so the people will come in and they do these aerobics in the morning to warm up
0:03:32 their bodies for the day, and they have the robots do the aerobics with their arms with
0:03:37 the people so that they’ll be perceived more like colleagues and less as machines.
0:03:40 People are more accepting of the technology.
0:03:45 People enjoy working with it more, and I think it’s really important to acknowledge this
0:03:48 emotional connection because you can harness it too.
0:03:50 So we know we have this tendency.
0:03:57 If we think about being aware of it and being able to foster it or diminish it, what are
0:04:00 some of the ways in which we negotiate those relationships?
0:04:05 My focus is trying to think about what that means ethically, what that means in terms
0:04:12 of maybe changing human behavior, what challenges we might want to anticipate.
0:04:18 We’re seeing a lot of interesting use cases for social robots that are specifically designed
0:04:22 to get people to treat them like living things, to develop an emotional connection.
0:04:29 One of my favorite current use cases for this technology is a replacement for animal therapy.
0:04:30 We have therapeutic robots.
0:04:35 They’re used as medical devices with dementia patients or in nursing homes.
0:04:39 I saw an article about that recently, specifically with people with dementia.
0:04:41 Yeah, there’s a baby seal that’s very popular.
0:04:42 That’s right.
0:04:43 That’s the one I read about.
0:04:45 A lot of people think it’s creepy.
0:04:50 We’re giving old people robots and having them nurture something that’s not alive.
0:04:57 But then you look at some of the advantages of having them have this experience when their
0:05:00 lives have been reduced to being taken care of by other people.
0:05:04 It’s actually an important psychological experience for them to have.
0:05:10 They’ve been able to use these robots as alternatives to medication for calming distressed patients.
0:05:15 This isn’t a replacement for human care and that’s also not how it’s being used.
0:05:20 It’s really being used as a replacement for animal therapy where we can’t use real animals
0:05:25 because people will consistently treat them more like a living thing than a device.
0:05:29 What is the initial interaction like when you hold something like that?
0:05:31 Is there a prelude that’s necessary?
0:05:36 Do you have to educate a little bit those patients or do they just put the robot seal
0:05:38 in their arms?
0:05:43 The most clever robotic design doesn’t require any prelude or anything because you will
0:05:46 automatically respond to the cues.
0:05:48 The baby seal is very simple.
0:05:53 It just makes these little cute sounds and movements and responds to your touch and will
0:05:56 purr a little bit.
0:06:02 It’s very intuitive and it’s also not trying to be a cat or anything that you would be
0:06:07 more intimately familiar with because no one has actually held a baby seal before.
0:06:11 It’s much easier to suspend your disbelief and just go with it.
0:06:18 What are some of the very broad umbrella concerns that we want to be thinking about as we’re
0:06:20 watching these interactions develop?
0:06:24 A lot of my work has been around empathy and violence towards robotic objects.
0:06:28 Are we already being violent towards them?
0:06:29 Sometimes.
0:06:35 There was this robot called Hitchbot that hitchhiked all the way across the entire country of Canada,
0:06:38 just relying on the kindness of strangers.
0:06:42 It was trying to do a road trip through the US and it made it to Philadelphia and then
0:06:44 it got vandalized beyond repair.
0:06:49 Of course, Philadelphia, by the way, because I’m from New Jersey.
0:06:55 As you’re telling me this story, I’m already imagining this alien life doing a little journey
0:06:56 through the world.
0:07:01 I’m completely projecting this narrative onto it and that was the interesting thing about
0:07:02 the story.
0:07:06 It wasn’t that the robot got beat up, but it was people’s response to that, that they
0:07:12 were empathizing with this robot that was just trying to hitchhike around and that it
0:07:15 got … People were so sad when this robot got …
0:07:17 It’s poor little stranger in a strange land.
0:07:18 Yeah.
0:07:22 There was news about this all over the world that hit international news.
0:07:23 What did we learn from that?
0:07:26 Why is it interesting that we empathize with them?
0:07:31 Even more interesting to me is the question, how does interacting with these very life-like
0:07:35 machines influence our behavior?
0:07:42 Could you use them therapeutically to help children or prisoners or help improve people’s
0:07:43 behavior?
0:07:49 Then the flip side of that question is, could it be desensitizing to people to be violent
0:07:53 towards robotic objects that behave in a really life-like way?
0:07:59 Is that a healthy outlet for people’s violent behavior to go and beat up robots that respond
0:08:04 in a really life-like way, or is that training our cruelty muscles?
0:08:09 Isn’t that a new version of almost the old video game argument?
0:08:11 How is it shifting?
0:08:17 It’s the exact same question, which by the way, I don’t think we’ve ever really resolved.
0:08:24 We mostly decided that people can probably compartmentalize, but children we’re not
0:08:29 sure about, and so we restrict very violent games to adults.
0:08:36 So we’ve decided that we might want to worry about the kids, but adults can probably handle
0:08:37 it.
0:08:44 Now, robots, I think, make us need to re-ask the question because they have this visceral
0:08:52 physicality that we know from research people respond differently to than things on a screen.
0:08:57 There’s a question of whether we can compartmentalize as well with robots, specifically because
0:09:01 they are so present in the world with us.
0:09:06 So do you think that’s because it’s almost a somatic relationship to them?
0:09:10 Will it matter the same way when we are immersed in, say, virtual reality?
0:09:15 I mean, as virtual reality gets more physical, I think that the two worlds merge.
0:09:23 And so even though the answer could very well be people can still distinguish between what’s
0:09:29 fake and what’s real, and just because they beat up their robot doesn’t mean that they’re
0:09:33 going to go and beat up a person or that their barrier to doing that is lower, but we don’t
0:09:34 know.
0:09:35 How do you start looking at that?
0:09:39 What are the details that start giving you an inkling one way or the other?
0:09:45 The way that I think we’re beginning to start to get at the question is just trying to figure
0:09:48 out what those relationships look like at first.
0:09:54 So I’ve done some work on how do people’s tendencies for empathy relate to their hesitation
0:09:57 to hit a robot?
0:10:01 Just to try and establish that people do empathize with the robots because we don’t…
0:10:02 We have to show that first.
0:10:04 Yeah, we have to show that first.
0:10:05 It’s so interesting.
0:10:10 We all know what that feeling is, but to show, to demonstrate, to model it, and then see
0:10:17 it and recognize it in our kind of research experimentation, how do you actually categorize
0:10:19 the response of empathy?
0:10:24 One of the things we did was have people come into the lab and smash robots with hammers
0:10:31 and time how long they hesitated to smash the robot when we told them to smash it.
0:10:36 Did you give them a framework around this experiment or just have them walk in and just
0:10:37 start?
0:10:38 Definitely.
0:10:42 They did not know that they were going to be asked to hit the robot and we did psychological
0:10:48 empathy testing with them to try and establish a baseline for how they scored on empathic
0:10:53 concern generally, but also we had a variety of conditions.
0:10:59 So what we were trying to look at was a difference, for example, in would people hesitate more
0:11:05 if the robot had a name and a backstory versus if it was introduced to them as an object?
0:11:08 Oh, well, presumably the name and the backstory, right?
0:11:09 Yeah.
0:11:15 Yeah, not a huge surprise that when the robot’s name is Frank, people hesitate more.
0:11:17 So sorry, Frank.
0:11:25 We actually tried measuring slight changes in the sweat on their skin to see if they
0:11:29 were more physically aroused.
0:11:33 Unfortunately, those sensors were really unreliable, so we couldn’t get reliable data from that.
0:11:39 We tried coding the facial expressions, which was also difficult.
0:11:43 That’s what I was wondering about, because as one human, reading another human, you do
0:11:46 have some sense, right?
0:11:52 And I have to say the videos of this experiment are much more compelling than just the hesitation
0:11:59 data because people really did, like one woman was looking at this robot, which was a very
0:12:05 simple, looked kind of like a cockroach, was just a thing that moved around like an insect.
0:12:10 And so this one woman is holding the mallet and stealing herself, and she’s muttering
0:12:11 to herself.
0:12:12 It’s just a bug.
0:12:13 It’s just a bug.
0:12:21 So the videos were compelling, but we just didn’t find it easy enough to code them in
0:12:25 a way that would be scientifically sound or reliable.
0:12:27 So we relied just on the timing of the hesitation.
0:12:33 Other studies have measured people’s brainwaves while they watch videos of robots being tortured.
0:12:36 So there are a bunch of different ways that people have tried to get at this.
0:12:42 So when we start learning about our capacity for violence towards robots, are you thinking
0:12:48 about that in terms of what it teaches us back about humans or about what going forward,
0:12:50 the reason we need to know this?
0:12:56 We are learning actually more about human psychology as we watch people interact with
0:13:02 these machines that don’t communicate back to us in an authentic way.
0:13:08 So that’s interesting, but I think that it’s mainly important because we’re already facing
0:13:12 some questions of regulating robots.
0:13:16 For example, there’s been a lot of moral panic around sex robots.
0:13:21 We already need to be answering the question, do we want to allow this type of technology
0:13:23 to exist and be used and be sold?
0:13:27 Do we want to only allow for it in therapeutic contexts?
0:13:29 Do we want to ban it completely?
0:13:34 And the fact is we have no evidence to guide us in what we should be doing.
0:13:39 So it’s all coming down to the same question of like, is this desensitizing or is this
0:13:40 enhancing basically?
0:13:41 Yeah.
0:13:48 Unfortunately, a lot of the discussions are just fueled by superstition or moral panic
0:13:53 or in this context, a lot of it is science fiction and pop culture.
0:14:00 And our constant tendency to compare robots to humans and look at them as human replacements
0:14:04 versus thinking a little bit more outside of the box and viewing them as something that’s
0:14:07 more supplemental to humans.
0:14:10 Do we have a model for what that even might be?
0:14:18 I’ve been trying to argue that animals might be the better analogy to these machines that
0:14:24 can sense and think and make autonomous decisions and learn and that we treat like they’re alive,
0:14:31 but we know that they’re not actually alive or feel anything or have emotions or can make
0:14:33 moral decisions.
0:14:36 They are still controlled by humans.
0:14:37 Property.
0:14:38 Property.
0:14:39 They’re property.
0:14:44 And throughout history, we’ve treated some animals as property, as tools.
0:14:50 Some animals we’ve turned into our companions and I think that that is how we’re going
0:14:52 to start integrating robotic technology as well.
0:14:56 We’re going to be treating a lot of it like products and tools and property.
0:15:01 And some of it we’re going to become emotionally attached to and we might integrate in different
0:15:02 ways.
0:15:08 But we definitely should stop thinking about robots as human replacements and start thinking
0:15:14 about how to harness them as a partner that has a different skill set.
0:15:18 So while you’re talking, I’m thinking about the incredibly fraught space of how we relate
0:15:20 to animals.
0:15:25 Some people might argue that since that’s such a gray area as it is and we’re always
0:15:30 feeling our way, and that model is always changing, it almost sounds like it just makes
0:15:33 it messier in a way.
0:15:38 And I also think there’s a way in which we have this primal instinct of how to relate
0:15:39 to animals.
0:15:44 Do you think we have the same kind of seed for a primal relationship with robots there?
0:15:45 I think we do.
0:15:51 I think that ironically, we’re learning more about our relationship to animals through
0:15:56 interacting with robots because we’re realizing that we’re complete hypocrites.
0:15:57 Oh.
0:15:58 Well, yeah.
0:16:07 I think we fancy ourselves as caring about the inner biological workings of the animals
0:16:09 and whether animals can suffer.
0:16:12 And we actually don’t care about any of that.
0:16:15 We care about what animals we relate to.
0:16:19 And a lot of that is cultural and emotional, and a lot of that is based on which animals
0:16:21 are cute.
0:16:26 For example, in the United States, we don’t eat horses.
0:16:31 It’s considered taboo, whereas in a lot of parts of Europe, people are like, well, horses
0:16:33 and cows are both delicious.
0:16:35 Why would you distinguish between the two?
0:16:38 There’s no inherent biological reason to distinguish.
0:16:39 Right.
0:16:40 And by the way, we boil them into glue.
0:16:46 And yet culturally, we feel this like bond with horses in the U.S. as this majestic beast,
0:16:50 and it seems so wrong to us to eat them.
0:16:53 The history of animal rights is full of stories like this.
0:17:01 Like, the Save the whales campaign didn’t start until people recorded whales singing.
0:17:05 Before that, people did not care about whales, but then once we heard that they can sing
0:17:09 and make this beautiful music, we were like, oh, we must save these beautiful creatures
0:17:12 that we can now suddenly relate to.
0:17:15 Because it needs to be about us kind of on some deep level.
0:17:21 The sad but important realization is that we relate to things that are like us and we
0:17:26 can build robots that are like that, and we are going to relate to those robots more than
0:17:27 to other robots.
0:17:33 So it’s a principle almost of design thinking, then, when you think about, well, I want this
0:17:40 robot to have a relationship to humans like cattle pulling a plow.
0:17:44 It gives you a sort of vision of a different spectrum of relationships for starters.
0:17:47 I mean, we’ve even tried to design animals accordingly.
0:17:53 We’ve bred dogs to look specific ways, so that we relate more to them.
0:17:57 And the interesting thing about robots is that we have even more freedom to design them
0:18:00 in compelling ways than we do with animals.
0:18:02 It takes a while to breed animals.
0:18:03 Yeah, generations.
0:18:11 Yeah, so I think we’re going to see the same types of manipulations of the robot breeds.
0:18:16 Why would you go down on that spectrum to the lesser relationships when it’s something
0:18:19 that is performing a service to humans?
0:18:25 If it’s not directly harmful to have people develop an emotional attachment, it’s probably
0:18:27 not a bad idea to do.
0:18:34 But a lot of the potential for robots right now is in taking over tasks that are dirty,
0:18:36 dull, and dangerous.
0:18:42 And so if we’re using robots as tools to go do the thing, it might make sense to design
0:18:45 them in a way that’s less compelling to people so that we don’t feel bad for them when they’re
0:18:48 doing the dirty, dull, dangerous work.
0:18:50 There are contexts where it can be harmful.
0:18:55 So for example, you have in the military, you have soldiers who become emotionally attached
0:18:57 to the robots that they work with.
0:19:01 And that can be anything from inefficient to dangerous because you don’t want them hesitating
0:19:06 for even a second to use these machines the way that they’re intended to be used.
0:19:07 Like police dogs.
0:19:09 That’s a great analogy.
0:19:16 If you become too attached to the thing that you’re working with, if it’s intended to
0:19:21 go into harm’s way in your place, for example, which is a lot of how we’re using robots
0:19:26 these days, bomb disposal units, stuff like that, you don’t want soldiers becoming emotionally
0:19:33 affected by sending the robot into harm’s way because they could risk their lives.
0:19:37 So it’s really important to understand that these emotional connections we form with these
0:19:40 machines can have real world consequences.
0:19:48 Another interesting area is responsibility for harm because it does get a lot of attention
0:19:51 from policymakers and from the general public.
0:19:56 With robots generally, there’s a lot of throwing up our hands, like how can we possibly hold
0:20:00 someone accountable for this harm if the robot did something no one could anticipate?
0:20:09 I think we’re forgetting that we have a ton of history with animals where we have things
0:20:14 that we’ve treated as property that can make autonomous unpredictable decisions that can
0:20:15 cause harm.
0:20:21 So there’s this whole body of legislation that we can look to, basically.
0:20:22 Yes.
0:20:26 The smorgasbord of different solutions we’ve had is really compelling.
0:20:34 The Romans even had rules around, if your oxen tramples the neighbor’s field, the neighbor
0:20:40 might actually be able to appropriate your oxen or even kill your oxen.
0:20:47 We’ve had animal trials, I talked about that in a podcast with Peter Leeson about the trials
0:20:49 of the rats for decimating crops.
0:20:56 There’s different ways even today that we like to assign responsibility for harm.
0:21:01 There’s the very pragmatic, okay, how do we compensate the victim of harm?
0:21:05 How do we hold the person who caused the harm accountable so that there’s an incentive to
0:21:07 not do it again?
0:21:11 And a lot of that is done through civil liability.
0:21:19 There’s also, however, criminal law that is kind of a primitive concept when you think
0:21:20 about it.
0:21:26 There was just this case in India where an old man was stoned to death with bricks by
0:21:29 monkeys who were intentionally flinging bricks.
0:21:35 And the family tried to get the police to do something about the monkeys and hold the
0:21:39 monkeys criminally accountable for what happened.
0:21:42 Just because of that human assigning of blame?
0:21:50 Yes, because it wasn’t enough to just have some sort of monetary compensation.
0:21:56 They really wanted these monkeys to suffer a punishment for what they had done.
0:21:59 And I know it seems silly, but we do sometimes have that tendency.
0:22:05 So it’s interesting to think about ways that we might actually want to hold machines themselves
0:22:08 accountable and ways that that’s problematic as well.
0:22:13 So can you illustrate what that would look like with robots when we think about those
0:22:15 different ways of assigning responsibility?
0:22:16 Yeah.
0:22:22 So for example, the way that we regulate pit bulls currently in some countries is really
0:22:23 interesting.
0:22:29 Austria has decided there are some breeds of dogs that we are going to place much stricter
0:22:35 requirements on than just the other dog breeds.
0:22:41 So you need to get what’s basically the equivalent of a driver’s license to walk these dogs.
0:22:46 They have to have special collars and they have to be registered.
0:22:50 And you could imagine for certain types of robots having a registry, having requirements,
0:22:57 having a different legal accountability, like strict liability versus, “Oh, did I intend
0:23:00 to cause this harm or did I cause it through neglect?”
0:23:05 The way that we distinguish, for example, between wild animals and pets.
0:23:10 If you have a tiger and the tiger kills the postal service worker, that’s going to be
0:23:14 your fault regardless of how careful you were with the tiger because we say having a tiger
0:23:16 is just inherently dangerous.
0:23:21 It’s almost, the model is sort of developing different ideas around certain categories
0:23:28 and groups of the way we relate to them, depending on whether those relationships are based on
0:23:35 then sort of our emotional narratives around it or evidence based becomes really important.
0:23:41 The heart of it is that we need to recognize that social robots could have an impact on
0:23:46 people’s behavior and that it’s something that we might actually need to regulate.
0:23:51 One of the interesting conversations that’s happening right now is around autonomous weapon
0:23:57 systems and accountability for harm in settings of war, where we have war crimes, but they
0:24:00 require intentionality.
0:24:06 And if a robot is committing a war crime, then there’s maybe not this moral accountability.
0:24:10 But wouldn’t it be an obvious whoever programmed and owns the robot?
0:24:16 Because you need someone to have intentionally caused this rather than accidentally.
0:24:22 The thing about robots is that they can actually now make decisions based on the data that
0:24:30 they gather that isn’t a glitch in the code, but is something that we didn’t foresee happening.
0:24:36 We’ve used autonomous unpredictable agents as weapons in war previously.
0:24:45 For example, the Soviets, they trained dogs to run under tanks, enemy tanks, and they
0:24:51 had explosives attached to them and they were meant to blow up the tanks.
0:24:53 And a bunch of things went wrong.
0:25:00 So first of all, they had trained the dogs on their own tanks, which means that the
0:25:09 dogs would sometimes blow up their own tanks instead of the enemy tanks.
0:25:15 They didn’t train the dogs to be able to deal with some of the noise on the battlefield
0:25:21 and the shooting, so the dogs got scared and would run back to their handlers with these
0:25:27 explosives attached to them, and the handlers had to end up shooting the dogs.
0:25:31 And we’re not perfect at programming robots either, so there’s a lot of things that can
0:25:37 go wrong that don’t necessarily, they’re not glitches in code.
0:25:40 It’s unanticipated consequences.
0:25:44 So when we’re thinking about regulating things, I think that’s a pretty good analogy to look
0:25:50 at the history of how we’ve handled these things in the past and who we’ve held accountable.
0:25:55 The interesting thing that occurs to me is how do we both acknowledge our human emotional
0:25:59 attachment and yet not let it direct us too much?
0:26:00 What’s that balance like?
0:26:02 Step one is probably awareness, right?
0:26:07 But is it something we can manage and navigate or is it kind of beyond our control?
0:26:14 I think we struggle with that culturally as well, because we have this Judeo-Christian
0:26:19 distinction, like we have this clear line between things that are alive and things that are
0:26:24 not alive, whereas in some other countries, they don’t necessarily make that distinction.
0:26:29 Like in Japan, they have this whole history of Shintoism and treating objects as things
0:26:30 with souls.
0:26:39 And so it’s, I think, easier for them to view robots as just another thing with a soul and
0:26:44 they don’t have this contradiction inside themselves of, “Oh, I’m treating this thing
0:26:46 like a living thing, but it’s just a machine.”
0:26:49 Oh, that’s so fascinating because I would have thought it would be the other way.
0:26:53 If you think everything has a soul, it’s sort of harder to disentangle, but you’re saying
0:26:57 you sort of are desensitized to it in a way.
0:27:02 Or you’re more used to viewing everything as connected but different.
0:27:07 And so, you know, you still face the same design challenges of how do you get people
0:27:12 to treat robots like tools in settings where you don’t want them to get emotionally attached
0:27:13 to them.
0:27:17 So those design challenges still exist, but I think as a society, you’re not also dealing
0:27:21 with this contradiction of, “I want to treat this thing like a machine, but I’m treating
0:27:22 it differently.”
0:27:27 Right, the sort of ethical wrappers around this that we need to be aware of when we’re
0:27:32 starting to introduce these different types of interactions as these relationships become
0:27:33 more sophisticated.
0:27:36 Thank you so much for joining us on the A16Z podcast.
0:27:36 Thanks for having me.
with Kate Darling (@grok_) and Hanne Tidnam (@omnivorousread)
We already know that we have an innate tendency to anthropomorphize robots. But beyond just projecting human qualities onto them, as we begin to share more and more spaces, social and private, what kind of relationships will we develop with them? And how will those relationships in turn change us?
In this Valentine’s Day special, Kate Darling, Researcher at MIT Labs, talks with a16z’s Hanne Tidnam all about our emotional relations with robots. From our lighter sides — affection, love, empathy, and support — to our darker sides, what will these new kinds of relationships enhance or de-sensitize in us? Why does it matter that we develop these often intense attachments to these machines that range from tool to companion — and what do these relationships teach us about ourselves, our tendencies and our behaviors? What kinds of models from the past can we look towards to help us navigate the ethics and accountability that come along with these increasingly sophisticated relationships with robots?
-
322: My 5 Favorite Books of the Year and My Top Takeaways from Each
“We are simultaneously gods and worms.”—Abraham Maslow
Power plus humility, right? It’s a great combination and something to keep in mind as we try and build our businesses.
We can accomplish amazing things, and yet, we’re gone in a flash. Mere blips on the historical radar.
But let’s be the gods of our side hustle universe today, and focus on shaping that business in a way that best serves ourselves and others.
In this special solo edition of The Side Hustle Show, I’m breaking down my Top 5 books from last year, and the actions I took (or am taking) as a result of reading them.
Hopefully there are a few nuggets you can borrow!
Full Show Notes: My 5 Favorite Books of the Year and My Top Takeaways from Each
-
367. The Future of Meat
Global demand for beef, chicken, and pork continues to rise. So do concerns about environmental and other costs. Will reconciling these two forces be possible — or, even better, Impossible™?
-
a16z Podcast: Cryptonetworks as Emerging Economies (Done Right?)
AI transcript
0:00:05 The content here is for informational purposes only, should not be taken as legal business
0:00:10 tax or investment advice or be used to evaluate any investment or security and is not directed
0:00:15 at any investors or potential investors in any A16Z fund. For more details, please see
0:00:21 a16z.com/disclosures. Hi everyone, welcome to the A6Z podcast. I’m
0:00:26 Sonal. Today we have another one of our podcast on the road episodes with guests from New
0:00:33 York City on the topic of crypto, but more broadly on crypto networks as emerging economies.
0:00:38 This conversation goes into the super interesting nuances of structuring these networks to avoid
0:00:43 some of the failings we’ve seen in the monetary and fiscal policies of traditional economies,
0:00:49 including debating how to empower users when it comes to risk, but also how to better distribute
0:00:54 access in terms of who captures value from networks. We then also discovered different
0:00:59 mindsets for the governance of these networks, which are really crypto economic systems,
0:01:04 especially as they evolve and grow more mainstream over time. Joining us to have this conversation,
0:01:09 we have two guests, our friends at Placeholder VC. Chris Berniske, who formerly led ARC Invest
0:01:13 Crypto Efforts, has written a lot about financial modeling influence frameworks for analyzing
0:01:18 crypto and co-wrote a book on crypto assets, and Joel Monegro, who before starting Placeholder
0:01:23 with Chris was an analyst at USV, where he helped develop their early blockchain theses
0:01:28 prior to that, he managed the Dominican Republic’s government office in charge of developing
0:01:32 the country’s national and digital economy technology agenda. I share all that as key
0:01:36 context for the conversation that follows. And last but not least, we have two of our
0:01:41 partners from A6 and Z Crypto, Jesse Walden and Dennis Nazarov, formerly co-founders
0:01:45 of MediaChain, which was acquired by Spotify, Jesse and Dennis interview our guests and
0:01:50 also add their perspectives in the discussion and debate. On that note, the content here
0:01:57 is for informational purposes only and should not be taken as legal business tax or investment
0:02:03 advice or be used to evaluate any investment or security. It is not directed at any investors
0:02:10 or potential investors in any fund. For more details, please also see a6nzcrypto.com/disclosures.
0:02:15 Before the discussion goes into what it takes to design such crypto economic systems at
0:02:20 scale from value capture to risk to governance, they first quickly begin with the fundamental
0:02:26 concept of layers in a stack of protocols and decentralized applications. The first
0:02:31 voice you’ll hear is Joel followed by Chris’s and then Jesse and Dennis joins in later.
0:02:35 You can think about it from an engineering point of view and how different kinds of
0:02:40 software are layered on top of each other. You can think about it also from a more social
0:02:46 point of view. Layer one is more machine work and layer two is more human work. And as you
0:02:51 transition from layer one to layer two, then you end up with lighter weight models because
0:02:55 you don’t have the capital cost of the machines to actually do the work, to store the files,
0:03:00 to mine the transactions. What we see at layer two are more abstract units of work that require
0:03:06 human judgment. And there the cost is harder to model because it’s harder to quantify what
0:03:10 is the value that goes into performing some unit of work. And that unit of work can be
0:03:16 anything from curating content to making a governance decision. All of those things are
0:03:21 very difficult to put in a spreadsheet model, but we have the aid of the invisible hand
0:03:26 in a way and that’s helping us figure out what human work is worth. I think the infatuation
0:03:31 with layer one comes from it being much easier to understand the cost and value relationship
0:03:35 between providing a service and consuming a service. It gets harder as you move up the
0:03:40 layers. Once you get into the realm of human work is when you start to really imagine that
0:03:44 there are different ways in which crypto can really change the way we do things.
0:03:48 I think as we go up higher in these layers we’re going to see different incentivization
0:03:54 and therefore value capture mechanisms. Layer one, the priority is security because that’s
0:03:59 basically our clearing and settlement layer. And so we’ve really seen Bitcoin prioritize
0:04:05 security or Ethereum. And because if we build all these layers on top of an insecure layer
0:04:11 one then we’re screwed, right? And then as we move up the stack it’s less about that
0:04:18 machine security say and more about how do you incentivize the economic actors to perform
0:04:23 the service that you’ve promised to provide. And the only way that that ends up being a
0:04:28 service that the end user uses is either if it’s cheaper than existing services that
0:04:32 you can get from the centralized model but on par in terms of user experience or it’s
0:04:38 a fundamentally new experience or service and this is the only place I can get it there’s
0:04:43 the access tokens where basically there’s demand of what I find interesting about an
0:04:47 access token is historically we’ve thought of tokens as needing to connect the supply
0:04:52 side and demand side. An access token really just focuses on the supply side and it can
0:04:56 have a fixed supply and there can be scarcity because basically if the supply side needs
0:05:01 that token to perform the service and performing the service is a profitable activity for them
0:05:06 then there will be a clamoring to get a hold of that token and that drives its own scarcity
0:05:11 and that’s slightly easier to model you can actually use discounted cash flow model to
0:05:17 approximate the value of that token and the demand side can pay in fiat if they want and
0:05:21 I think we’ll increasingly see this where the demand side is going to just pay in whatever
0:05:26 asset they want they don’t need to interface with crypto assets from a day to day perspective
0:05:31 but you can still have value in a work token that organizes the supply side and induces
0:05:34 a competition around being able to provide that service.
0:05:39 So in the model you described Chris we call it the taxi medallion model what’s interesting
0:05:44 about it is there’s one token that is the right to do the work and the other token which
0:05:49 is the payment token and so as you said it’s you can do sort of a cash flow analysis on
0:05:54 what the work token is going to earn and this differs from the base layer where you know
0:06:00 today most of the layer one blockchains use one token for both rewarding the supply side
0:06:05 and for the demand side to consume the service and I’m curious what do you guys think the
0:06:13 implications of moving to work token model are is there any sort of implications for
0:06:17 users and suppliers not being aligned around the same token.
0:06:23 Well the thing that’s really scary about this trend to create dual token systems where one
0:06:27 token gives you access to the supply side or a right to participate in the supply side
0:06:31 and another one into being the payment token whether it’s another token that it’s created
0:06:36 by the crypto network or something like ETH or any other one is that you were doing the
0:06:42 same thing that we did with the world economy which is that we separated currency and capital
0:06:47 the moment that we moved into a fiat currency model in modern capitalism.
0:06:53 We have two major kind of asset types we have capital and we have that and currencies are
0:06:57 really a form of debt at the end of the day and backtracking a little bit the reason we
0:07:01 separated currency from capital is because the transaction velocity of capital is very
0:07:08 low the transaction velocity of a dollar is very high and so as the economy grows exchanging
0:07:12 gold or land or just a barter system is not going to work and so we needed currencies
0:07:19 to accelerate economic growth so far so good the problem is that capital and currencies
0:07:24 respond very differently to economic growth capital appreciates together with economic
0:07:28 growth and currencies actually depreciate as an economy grows.
0:07:34 Inflation is commonly thought of as the printing of new money but really a more traditional
0:07:40 definition of inflation is increases in prices over time as a result of economic growth and
0:07:45 capital as an asset type appreciates as the economy grows because it is more scarce than
0:07:50 currency currency we print more of it to keep up with inflation to keep prices stable and
0:07:53 that’s how they end up devaluing over time because we’re creating more and more and more
0:07:58 what happens over time then is that actually capital becomes more and more concentrated
0:08:02 because its transaction velocity is so low and the problem with that is that we end up
0:08:07 with a lot of people living their lives in in currency and very few people living their
0:08:08 lives in capital.
0:08:13 What part of the promise of crypto networks at least to me is that we are able to combine
0:08:18 currency and capital into a single asset so that then we don’t get the same kind of income
0:08:24 inequality or wealth inequality being created as any individual crypto network grows and
0:08:29 the risk of separating the access token or the work token from the currency token is
0:08:34 that the people who accumulated the access tokens early on that group becomes increasingly
0:08:39 concentrated over time as the economy grows or as the crypto network grows the value of
0:08:44 combining the two. If you have a single token that is both a supply site token and a payment
0:08:50 token in order for the supply site to provide its service it has to take payment in that
0:08:53 token so the token has to be in the user’s hands in order for them to actually consume
0:08:58 the service and so that creates a pressure to sell the work token or sell the capital
0:09:02 token as the network grows because otherwise you’re not going to get any customers. Everyone
0:09:06 in a crypto network can participate from the value created as opposed to just one segment.
0:09:12 I definitely agree there’s a risk to backtracking a little bit with the ethos of crypto separating
0:09:17 the work or the capital and currency. I think one thing even if we end up in a work token
0:09:23 world or taxi medallion world where we’ve separated capital and currency again at least
0:09:29 within those networks the one reassuring thing is that you can’t be a passive accumulator
0:09:35 of capital. You have to be more active like you stake the work token and then you have
0:09:40 to continue to provide work for the network to continue to collect cash flows.
0:09:43 So I would argue that that’s not entirely true and that’s because in these proof of
0:09:49 stake systems you often have the ability to delegate stake and so what happens there is
0:09:53 a marketplace emerges where there are people sitting on capital and they just point that
0:09:58 capital at a worker so it’s very much like taxi medallions work in New York City. They’re
0:10:02 mostly bought up by hedge funds and the like and then they hire drivers to go and drive
0:10:06 the cars and earn passive income on those medallions. And so I think that does speak
0:10:11 to Jule’s point that the separation of these two things does result in a concentration
0:10:17 of capital but I would argue that the flip side is that the users of the service don’t
0:10:22 have to take any risk. So when I get into a taxicab I don’t have to think about whether
0:10:28 Uber or Lyft are going to have a real big impact on the value of my medallion and the
0:10:33 future utility I’ll get out of it. So humans tend to think in one unit of account because
0:10:37 it’s just easier to reason about and you don’t want to be taking risk necessarily when you’re
0:10:42 buying a coffee or a pizza and that ends up going on to be worth millions of dollars.
0:10:49 And so there is this sort of simplicity in the tax now in versus currency model that
0:10:54 I think it’s hard to get away from just because of human nature.
0:10:59 I argue that risk is good because you can’t create value without creating risk. And again
0:11:04 it’s that same kind of thinking that led to the world where we are today. It’s much simpler
0:11:09 to have everyone use dollars because no one has to think about how the markets are moving
0:11:12 and how your value is changing over time. Rather you trust the government. You trust
0:11:18 that they’re going to maintain a certain monetary policy such that you hope that your
0:11:22 hundred thousand dollars today is going to maintain a certain degree of purchasing power.
0:11:28 The problem with that is that by not allowing people to take risks in a way then we’ve cheated
0:11:33 them away from capturing some of the upside of the value. And I think it’s time to rethink
0:11:39 how we think about risk for people more broadly. If we prevent people or the science systems
0:11:44 that make it harder for people to take those risks and participate in the value then we’re
0:11:48 going to end up in the same world where we are today where the values concentrated amongst
0:11:52 those who took the greatest risks. Now obviously it can go really badly if you have a whole
0:11:55 bunch of risk spread a whole whole bunch of people and then everything comes crashing
0:12:00 down then you have a real problem. So it’s not that there isn’t value instability and
0:12:05 value in currencies that make it easier for consumers to go about their daily lives. But
0:12:09 I also don’t think we’re heading to a world where you buy your coffee with Bitcoin. I
0:12:14 also think that the overall argument of well we need to create these systems because otherwise
0:12:18 it’s too risky and then people are not going to use it. I think it’s a little not patronizing
0:12:23 but it underestimates people’s ability to make those decisions for themselves.
0:12:29 I remember asking you about three four years ago whether it’s actually a good idea to make
0:12:35 your users investors because there’s a cognitive overhead that is associated with that. You’re
0:12:42 asking your users to be sophisticated about the underlying infrastructure powering their
0:12:48 daily experience and I think increasingly in in crypto we’re seeing that at least when
0:12:53 you have some skin in the game participants in these networks are willing to go in a little
0:12:58 bit deeper and the types of communities that emerge are on these projects are just fundamentally
0:13:02 different like people have a different relationship with the network. Ethereum participants own
0:13:08 the token and therefore have an emotional connection to the values of the infrastructure
0:13:13 and its goals and what it achieves. Sometimes. Yeah, to a fault sometimes and I think the
0:13:20 question is how scalable is this? Can we scale this model to the entire world or is it limited
0:13:26 to a subset of users who are sophisticated enough and want to take on that risk and so
0:13:31 just to push back a little bit on the idea that we will be able to scale this model sort
0:13:35 of all the way up. I think the idea of having this work token currency model it doesn’t
0:13:41 preclude power users from participating in the network and then through delegation the
0:13:45 owner of that token does not need to necessarily provide the work. So a power user can invest
0:13:51 in the success of the network that they’re using but it’s a choice and so I think there’s
0:13:56 flexibility both ways. On one side the assumption is that we should give risk to everyone and
0:14:00 that’s that optimal in the other side is we should let people choose. You can argue both
0:14:05 sides of the table and so what that tells me is let the people make the choice but then
0:14:09 that becomes a question of what’s the default. So you know we’ve all gone through a sign-up
0:14:14 form where the checkboxes are checked by default or not that opt you into certain things and
0:14:19 we’ve learned that people tend to stick with the default and so I would rather see a world
0:14:23 where the default is we’re all participating in the value. Yeah, any citizen can go and
0:14:27 open a brokerage account and buy stocks and participate in the market but most people
0:14:32 don’t because that’s not the default. So I think one thing that we can do here is actually
0:14:37 create a model and train another generation of users to think as users who are staked
0:14:41 in the network in a way that we really couldn’t before and the generational aspect I think
0:14:46 is very important because the other thing that’s going on here is that the way these
0:14:51 assets accrue value is very different to the way that other previous kinds of assets accrue
0:14:57 value. Previously in a more traditional world when we had companies go public it was a lot
0:15:02 of the same philosophy of you, you’re a customer of Walmart, Walmart goes public, you can buy
0:15:06 stock in Walmart and then every time that you go to Walmart and you’re paying with your
0:15:12 dollars you know there is some value accruing back to you as a shareholder of the company.
0:15:15 But in order to properly analyze an equity you have to go to business school and learn
0:15:19 how to do this kind of cash flows and how to figure out you know how to analyze whether
0:15:23 management is doing things correctly and so on. What’s different here is that we’re dealing
0:15:28 with these decentralized networks where if they’re properly constructed the value doesn’t
0:15:32 really necessarily depend on the actions of a management team but rather on the overall
0:15:33 network.
0:15:39 Yes, we were talking about the consumer perspective and them being a shareholder and that’s one
0:15:43 side of the argument, the other is from the developer and people who are actually building
0:15:44 these protocols.
0:15:49 So I want to take a step back because we’ve been saying user network participant those
0:15:57 kinds of things and I think that it really depends on which network participant we’re
0:15:58 referring to.
0:16:03 So early on in a network where it’s mostly the supply side right because the supply side
0:16:08 has to come on board to actually provision the asset and presumably the supply side is
0:16:15 going to be a much more sophisticated person at least in their understanding of the network
0:16:16 than the demand side.
0:16:20 At least as we scale out over the long term I think that’s an assumption we can make.
0:16:24 And so that supply side can tolerate that earlier risk because presumably they’re more
0:16:27 sophisticated and so that all makes sense.
0:16:32 Where I think we start to encounter more problems especially if crypto goes mainstream we will
0:16:38 have you know hundreds of millions billions of end users on the demand side and I think
0:16:43 it’s a stretch to ask the demand side to be an expert in the network.
0:16:46 The supply side this is different from our current equity environment.
0:16:52 If you set aside stock based comp traditionally an employee at a company doesn’t necessarily
0:16:54 have exposure to the upside of that company.
0:16:59 Stock based comp has changed that a lot but that employee mostly gets paid in fiat currency
0:17:03 which goes back to Joel’s point of you know they don’t get to participate in the capital
0:17:08 appreciation as much as the management and the concentrated owners of capital.
0:17:11 So for me that’s a big improvement.
0:17:18 Early on demand-siders they’ll be early adopters but I think as this space grows we will abstract
0:17:22 a lot of that complexity away from them and the demand side will just pay in whatever
0:17:27 they want to pay it be they in Kenya be they in the US be they in Korea you pay for the
0:17:32 service with whatever currency you want that ends up getting converted and the supply side
0:17:37 will get paid in the native asset of the network through whatever it may be.
0:17:41 But the key is that the supply side gets access to that risk and that capital appreciation
0:17:42 for me for me.
0:17:47 So I think an interesting sort of avenue to go down here is to again come back to this
0:17:51 idea of the different layers in the stack and how it may be different at each of them.
0:17:56 So at the base layer it makes a lot of sense for there to be sort of one currency or you
0:18:01 know because because you do really want to align the incentives of the supply side and
0:18:07 the users because it’s this very general substrate upon which you know like all all kinds of
0:18:11 more complex applications can be built but this because it’s very general you want there
0:18:17 to be this sort of network effect that everyone is everyone converges on the values and the
0:18:22 goal of this general substrate as you get further up the stack and you build more complex
0:18:28 applications something like a stable coin for example requires sort of more specialization
0:18:32 in terms of the type of work that’s being done and this is to Joel’s point earlier that
0:18:39 it’s it’s more human work and more specialization generally means more expertise.
0:18:45 And so once you get into those types of applications I think it becomes a little bit harder for everyday
0:18:49 users to be sophisticated about the work that’s going on behind the scenes.
0:18:54 People probably don’t need to understand how Ethereum computers you know determine consensus
0:18:59 but I think the difference is that in order for a stable coin to work it’s a much more
0:19:03 you know complicated system and it has parameters that need to be tuned and they probably need
0:19:08 to be tuned by experts whereas computation is deterministic it’s sort of a binary outcome
0:19:11 right or wrong and it can be verified by computers.
0:19:16 And so I would argue that the base layer of the system being more general lends itself
0:19:20 to this sort of single token model a little bit better but as you move further up the
0:19:24 stack I think you do want this separation between sort of the management and the users
0:19:27 because it requires expertise.
0:19:29 And that brings us to governance.
0:19:30 Right.
0:19:34 And maybe an analogy is the base layer sort of like a country it’s like you’re a citizen
0:19:40 of America you get to vote and participate in you know elections and to decide kind of
0:19:41 policy.
0:19:46 Taxation policy is the substrate for all economic activity built on top of America and then
0:19:51 there’s more specific corporations inside of America and they have their own governance
0:19:56 practices they have their own equity and then participating in them is much more specialized
0:20:01 but you have this broad substrate that everyone else builds on top of with different governance
0:20:02 parameters.
0:20:07 So I like to think of or we like to think of crypto networks as emerging economies and
0:20:13 what’s interesting about that is that if you compare crypto network to a country you start
0:20:18 to see a number of similarities there’s a currency that’s exchanged between buyers and
0:20:23 sellers there’s if you think of the executive team or the executive branch is the core development
0:20:28 team and you think of the blockchain as the court or the legislative system where you
0:20:32 know all the rules go there and then you have the supply side which are the miners or the
0:20:36 producers and you have the demand side which are the users who are consuming the service
0:20:39 that starts to look a lot like a small economy.
0:20:44 And then what’s cool about that is that you can use this model to think through whether
0:20:47 a crypto network is properly constructed or not.
0:20:52 So for example things that we’ve learned over time that we like to see in physical economies
0:20:58 like low degrees of corruption and sound monetary policies and fiscal policies and a rich supply
0:21:03 side and an active demand side it ends up getting us into the topic of governance because
0:21:08 one of the things that can determine the success of a national economy or not is how that economy
0:21:09 is governed.
0:21:14 There’s a broader conversation about where is the value of governance in crypto networks
0:21:18 and governance is a difficult topic because it is so broad but I’ll bring it even further
0:21:24 back to the history of information technology in the 50s and 60s.
0:21:27 That era was based around the hardware how quickly you could iterate on hardware and
0:21:31 how quickly could you get computers in the market and IBM won that war because they were
0:21:36 able to design custom computers for custom use cases faster than than anybody else.
0:21:40 That business started breaking down in the 70s and 80s following the introduction of
0:21:45 the microprocessor which consolidated a whole bunch of those circuits into a single part
0:21:49 that was widely available and that created two things.
0:21:53 It first it unbundled the hardware industry and we went from effectively one computer
0:21:58 manufacturer to dozens of PC manufacturers and so on.
0:22:01 But then what happened is that value moved one layer up to the software layer and so
0:22:05 we have Microsoft and the PC software boom of the 70s and 80s.
0:22:09 We saw that get built on top of the microprocessor standard or platform.
0:22:15 Fast forward to the end of the 80s and into the 90s and we went from having dozens of
0:22:22 independent software ventures to having Microsoft consolidating that entire ecosystem and building
0:22:27 its business on the basis of proprietary software and proprietary distribution of that software.
0:22:30 What happened in the 90s is we got two things.
0:22:35 We got the internet and we got Linux which was free software and free distribution and
0:22:38 so that directly challenged Microsoft.
0:22:43 And so we got into the web era where the value moved again one layer up to data which is
0:22:44 where we live today.
0:22:50 We have the big tech companies of today Google, Apple, Facebook, Amazon and so on.
0:22:54 Their main asset their main capital asset is all the data that they’ve been able to
0:22:56 accrue over time as people have used their service.
0:23:01 So we’ve been in this stage for about 20 years now and right on schedule we get the
0:23:07 arrival of a new open technology which are blockchains that directly challenge the proprietary
0:23:11 data business model just as the internet and Linux challenged the proprietary software
0:23:12 and distribution business model.
0:23:16 It gets into a question of okay if we see this pattern of value moving one layer up,
0:23:20 one layer up, one layer up and we’ve gone from hardware to software and from software
0:23:22 to data and now data is free.
0:23:23 What’s above data?
0:23:29 The layer that exists at a higher level and to us that’s governance because it becomes
0:23:33 a question of how do we manage, how do we control, how do we manipulate the data and
0:23:38 how do we agree on a single source of truth which is the whole thinking behind designing
0:23:40 these consensus systems.
0:23:44 The crypto networks at the end of the day are systems that we designed to arrive at a shared
0:23:49 understanding of what is the right data to observe in a world where all the data is open.
0:23:51 And ultimately that is a governance system.
0:23:57 With that model do you think the base layer, the computational substrate, does that become
0:23:58 a commodity?
0:24:02 How do you think about the value of the base layer and how governance of the base layer
0:24:05 relates to the governance of the applications on top of it?
0:24:11 I think we need to be careful of thinking of it statically because just as Joel just
0:24:15 went through there’s this evolution of value capture that we saw with information technology
0:24:22 and I think we will see an evolution of value capture within crypto where value will start
0:24:24 to move up the protocol stack.
0:24:29 Right now we’re focused a lot on developer protocols because we believe it’s the developer
0:24:35 era of crypto and those are the most valuable people and developer attention is the most
0:24:38 valuable resource I would argue within crypto right now.
0:24:44 And we may have this period of value accrual and developer facing networks which then may
0:24:48 become commoditized and shift up to more consumer facing protocols.
0:24:50 But it’s more that there’s this evolution.
0:24:53 So how do you justify that more concretely?
0:24:58 For example, two transactions can use the same amount of gas, they could use the same
0:25:04 amount of the computational resource of Ethereum, but their economic value can be drastically
0:25:05 different.
0:25:09 I mean that brings a question of there’s sort of this tragedy of the commons problem that
0:25:14 one user of the protocol derives way more value from this underlying substrate than
0:25:15 another.
0:25:19 We can compare the foundational layer of a blockchain smart contract platform and decentralized
0:25:23 applications being built on top of it to general cloud computing infrastructure such
0:25:30 as Azure or Google Cloud or Amazon AWS and all the super valuable kind of union or applications
0:25:31 built on top of it.
0:25:37 They all utilize this commodity layer and kind of pay for computation at the level of
0:25:42 the resource, but the value they derive from the cloud platform is immensely higher, hence
0:25:46 their market caps combined are much higher than the cloud platforms underneath them.
0:25:50 So I don’t think every layer one protocol will capture a ton of value.
0:25:53 I think most of them will get commoditized and the ones that don’t will be the ones that
0:25:59 become these stores of value for these really important settlement protocols within the
0:26:00 space.
0:26:05 But I think that as we move up past that, we could see these middleware protocols actually
0:26:09 have more scale than the underlying smart contract protocols.
0:26:13 Start now with the developer in the future with the consumer, but still largely in the
0:26:14 protocol layer.
0:26:18 And I mean, we’re talking about a multi-decadal evolution here, but an evolution nonetheless.
0:26:23 I have a different way of thinking about value, which is through the lens of cost.
0:26:27 And this goes back to Econ 101, one of the first things they teach you is marginal benefit
0:26:30 equals marginal cost at equilibrium.
0:26:36 And bringing that into the discussion of where does value accrue, then you can then extend
0:26:40 that and okay, value will accrue to where there is the highest cost.
0:26:42 And it doesn’t really matter where in the layer that is.
0:26:46 It matters more what is the kind of service that’s being provided and what is the cost
0:26:47 of that service.
0:26:49 And then the other dimension is scale.
0:26:54 I think people sometimes confuse commodity with value less.
0:26:58 You can have something that is a complete commodity like milk and still get enormous amounts of
0:27:03 scale that permit value to accrue at that layer regardless.
0:27:08 As you move up the different layers or you start thinking about where does value accrue
0:27:14 in different places, just bringing back the whole governance umbrella, making a decision.
0:27:15 What’s the value of a decision?
0:27:19 Well, it might be in precisely where they’re implementing it in the governance over the
0:27:24 standard and over the protocol over time, where perhaps over time as the protocol becomes
0:27:30 more important and the standard becomes more widespread, then the value or the cost of
0:27:33 making a protocol decision increases over time because it affects a greater number of
0:27:35 people.
0:27:39 And so that’s one way in which you can kind of use the lens of cost to kind of chase down
0:27:44 where value might accrue in different services or across an ecosystem.
0:27:51 I think one helpful analogy with the governance space and value accrue from the perspective
0:27:57 of cost, if you look at, for example, United States, the United States has a fixed supply
0:28:05 of one president, but the cost of being that president has grown over time as the network
0:28:08 of the United States has also grown over time.
0:28:12 And this is actually where I think fixed supply works in a governance token setting.
0:28:16 If you have a fixed supply of that asset, but the cost and value of governing that network
0:28:21 is going up, then so too should the cost per token of that asset.
0:28:23 And so that’s a useful analogy for thinking through it.
0:28:28 And just thinking about America being a substrate for businesses built on top of it, the incentives
0:28:35 there is that corporations that exist within America are taxed to fund that substrate.
0:28:38 Better infrastructure, all kinds of services.
0:28:42 And to my earlier point, that there is no kind of economic relationship in the same
0:28:46 way that there is in America between Ethereum, for example, and the applications built on
0:28:52 top of it, you could imagine that there is some way in protocol to say it’s an upgrade
0:29:00 to ERC 20 standard, that 10% of the tokens every quarter, it’s a tax that goes to fund
0:29:01 the base chain.
0:29:08 And maybe this is a way to solve the problem of how do we fund innovation of the base chain.
0:29:09 I’m curious what you think of that.
0:29:16 I think traditionally taxation is one of the mechanisms through which a currency can boot
0:29:17 strap value.
0:29:22 And this goes back to, for example, the shardless theory that the government has to spend the
0:29:25 currency first and get it into circulation and then collect taxation.
0:29:28 And so that kick starts the economic flywheel.
0:29:32 People are experimenting with different forms of taxation in the space.
0:29:35 And really a transaction fee is a form of tax.
0:29:43 But we haven’t seen direct taxation to fund core developers beyond the inflationary model.
0:29:47 And that’s really kind of taxation through senior age or dilution.
0:29:52 For example, there’s Zcash or Decred or some of these networks that are working with this
0:29:57 idea of, okay, part of the monetary policy, we’re going to mint out over time and Decred
0:30:03 allocates 10% of each Coinbase reward to the developer pool, which will be allocated through
0:30:05 governance and the community’s decision to write it.
0:30:07 That’s effectively a 10% tax.
0:30:10 And same with Zcash, it’s a 20, 30% tax.
0:30:14 And because it’s of the income, right, if you think of every time a new block is produced,
0:30:15 that’s income that’s going to the miners.
0:30:18 But 10% of that is coming back to development.
0:30:22 It’s an implicit as opposed to an explicit tax that then funds the network.
0:30:27 You know, if you start thinking about governance first through the lens of this idea of taxation,
0:30:31 you can think of your kind of analogy of we have a fixed supply of one precedent and then
0:30:35 we can figure out how much it’s cost to run for precedent over time and figure out, you
0:30:38 know, what’s the cost of that governance model.
0:30:41 But there’s something that we can observe more concretely, which is just a tax rate
0:30:43 over time in world economies.
0:30:49 And we have seen tax rates as a proportion of GDP increase over time, as GDP increases
0:30:54 because the cost of governing the economy grows together with the growth of the economy.
0:30:59 And so how we can translate that into crypto networks is thinking through what is the cost
0:31:04 of governing a crypto network and the cost of maintaining an economic system over time.
0:31:08 And how does that change as that network grows or contracts over time?
0:31:13 So again, we keep coming back to this conversation around different layers in the stack and we
0:31:17 did a whole podcast on this about how the emergence of base layer crypto networks are
0:31:24 like cities in that there’s a bunch of people that have a vested interest in the infrastructure
0:31:27 upon which they’re building and they’re pulling it in different directions.
0:31:30 But there’s actually at the birth of a lot of cities, there’s not this like formal process
0:31:35 for coordinating that it just consensus emerges to this very rough process.
0:31:39 A lot of these ideas around rough consensus and running code are from Venkatesh Rao’s
0:31:43 post on Breaking Smart, which we’ve referenced a number of times on the podcast and we keep
0:31:44 coming back to.
0:31:50 We also talked about the emergence of internet standards and specifically the internet engineering
0:31:55 task force was this loose group of academics and engineers that were working on base layer
0:32:00 internet protocols and they had this very formal policy to not have voting, but instead
0:32:05 sort of weekly coordinated consensus mechanism whereby people argued their points with strong
0:32:06 opinions.
0:32:10 It was sort of a robust and sort of scientific approach and the best ideas were converged
0:32:11 upon.
0:32:17 So it’s this idea that a rough consensus emerges from one strong opinions weekly held to running
0:32:20 code in order to form those opinions.
0:32:24 And that’s very much the governance model of Bitcoin and Ethereum today.
0:32:27 Other projects are taking a different approach with formal on chain governance.
0:32:32 I think our view is that the more general the network, in terms of the service that it’s
0:32:37 providing, the more it lends itself to this process of rough consensus.
0:32:43 If you go all the way down the stack down to IP protocol, it’s this very general protocol.
0:32:48 It’s completely un-opinionated about the packets that it’s moving from A to B and the rough
0:32:53 consensus process or work there, it’s very lightweight and easy to integrate.
0:32:59 I would make the argument that general computation platform would lend itself to that same process
0:33:04 because you want it to do this very general thing and a thing that is very deterministic.
0:33:07 It doesn’t require human subjectivity to validate.
0:33:11 Then as you go further up the stack, there are applications built on top of the substrate
0:33:17 and as Dennis made earlier, it’s like the businesses built on top of America.
0:33:19 Each of them are providing different services.
0:33:23 They require different expertise in order to provide those services.
0:33:27 I would make the argument that at that layer in the stack, governance does become important.
0:33:32 The expertise requires specialization and these applications need to be more dynamic and responsive
0:33:38 to their users versus general computation, which over time should hopefully remain fairly
0:33:43 consistent such that these applications can build on top without the rules changing on
0:33:44 them.
0:33:51 There are many factors that go into governance decision processes that are informal.
0:33:55 One factor is the original roadmap of the project.
0:34:01 Does this change fit within the original vision outlined by both the founders and the community?
0:34:04 In Bitcoin, there is a promise of 21 million Bitcoins.
0:34:05 That is very important to it.
0:34:09 Also, there’s figureheads, Vitalik, for example, has very strong opinions.
0:34:13 While people trust him, he is one of many voices in the community.
0:34:15 I think it’s not dictatorial.
0:34:19 He proposes changes and there’s a debate and a conversation.
0:34:25 The base layer today in a platform like Ethereum is both the medium of exchange and the reward
0:34:28 for the supply side of the network.
0:34:31 Importantly, the governance process is this process of rough consensus where there is
0:34:35 no default setting for upgrading the network.
0:34:41 This is an important connection to draw because the users of the network have an active interest
0:34:44 in how the network evolves.
0:34:47 They are incentivized to participate in this process of rough consensus.
0:34:52 Whereas an application built on top of Ethereum, that layer in the stack, the expertise required
0:34:57 may necessitate that the management of this organization, whether it’s a central company
0:35:02 or a loosely affiliated group of people all over the world, that those stakeholders have
0:35:04 that expertise in order to make those decisions.
0:35:06 I think this is a really critical difference.
0:35:08 The base layer is very general.
0:35:13 Users wanted to do this one thing and do it well, compute things in a deterministic way,
0:35:17 but as you get further up the stack, it becomes a lot harder to reason about those mechanics.
0:35:22 I’ve started to use the term power tokens instead of governance tokens to refer to tokens
0:35:28 that represent the power to change the rules or change the makeup of a crypto network or
0:35:32 at least one vote to change the rules of the crypto network.
0:35:36 One way that I like to describe it is that crypt economics are the rules of the game
0:35:41 and governance is the power to change the rules of the game.
0:35:46 My belief is that as the game becomes more valuable, then the power to change the rules
0:35:48 becomes more valuable as well.
0:35:52 That’s the umbrella that I like to use to think through what’s the value of power, what’s
0:35:54 the value of changing the rules of the game.
0:36:00 If power tokens were the only means of making decisions, it’s sort of a very heavy-handed
0:36:06 specific tool that if manipulated incorrectly, it will lead to negative outcomes.
0:36:13 This more informal process through hard forks, you also, in addition, have checks and balances
0:36:17 where, as you mentioned earlier, there are different classes of participants, the miners,
0:36:22 the developers, the users, different bodies of the government that developers proposed
0:36:23 the code.
0:36:28 It has to be agreed upon by the miners to implement it, so it’s a more multifaceted multi-stakeholder
0:36:33 operation as opposed to who owns the tokens gets to, and the other problem is it creates
0:36:34 a default.
0:36:41 If the network automatically upgrades into some specific version of the code, the catastrophic
0:36:45 scenarios are much worse because everyone opts into a default, whereas in this more
0:36:49 weak consensus model, everyone has to agree in a broader way.
0:36:53 I have a twist on rough consensus and running code, which is crypt economic consensus and
0:36:59 running code, and my take on it is rough consensus works well when you’re small, and when the
0:37:03 number of stakeholders is fairly small, when the IETF was working through these protocol
0:37:09 iterations, you didn’t have to find consensus amongst a very large group of people in terms
0:37:11 of who is really affected by these decisions.
0:37:15 Today, it’s a completely different kind of dynamic where the underlying protocols have
0:37:20 remained fairly stagnant, and all of the innovation in terms of use cases has happened above,
0:37:24 where governance is a lot more fluid in the sense that each individual application can
0:37:28 construct its environment or its system in the way they prefer.
0:37:34 But bringing these ideas back to crypto, there’s another model that I like to think about which
0:37:37 is on-chain governance, off-chain diplomacy.
0:37:42 So by off-chain diplomacy, I mean every time that a core developer team meets with each
0:37:47 other to make a decision, or a user or an application of that protocol wants to lobby
0:37:48 for a change.
0:37:54 The human process by which we arrive at proposals and ultimately decisions, you still have meetings
0:38:00 between people debating and arriving at decisions and proposing different ideas.
0:38:01 All sorts of issues can emerge, right?
0:38:06 You can have concentration in the power token that enables a small group of people to really
0:38:10 control the network, but you can have the same kind of dynamic today with rough consensus.
0:38:14 If you don’t have a formal process that allows everyone that they can participate in that
0:38:18 process, you can end up with a clique that effectively governs the network through their
0:38:21 own rough consensus and cuts out everyone else.
0:38:26 Let’s make sure everyone in the network has a fundamental right to participate in that
0:38:27 governance process.
0:38:32 And let’s have mechanisms for people to get together and have sophisticated discussions
0:38:33 about how decisions were made.
0:38:37 But let’s make them convince the community and convince the network that that is the
0:38:38 right thing to do.
0:38:44 I think also, if you don’t have formal governance mechanisms and clarity around it, you devolve
0:38:47 into governance by defection.
0:38:48 And we saw that with Bitcoin.
0:38:51 We’re not necessarily arguing for complicated governance.
0:38:59 We’re arguing for rules and transparency such that the network participants all understand
0:39:02 not only what the rules are, but how the rules are changed.
0:39:07 Yeah, I guess where we might diverge a bit is that we are arguing that the more general
0:39:11 the service of a crypto network, the more it should be ossified.
0:39:17 So again, coming back to this IP is ossified, Bitcoin has ossified, maybe a general computation
0:39:23 substrate is better ossified because it lends itself to the trust that the developers building
0:39:27 on top need in order to feel comfortable building there.
0:39:31 However, those applications that developers build because they’re complex and dynamic
0:39:35 and interfacing with end users need to be able to change.
0:39:41 And in order for them to do so, a formal governance process is probably necessary.
0:39:45 The default is to take whatever the coin holders vote upon and upgrade the system.
0:39:50 And so I think one of the assumptions is that the token holders participating in the vote
0:39:56 and prior to that participating in the diplomacy are experts and have the best interests of
0:39:58 their users in mind.
0:40:01 Their interests are hopefully aligned with their end users.
0:40:03 And they pay for it if they mess up through dilution.
0:40:04 Right.
0:40:05 That’s right.
0:40:09 And so the incentives are tightly coupled so that the experts make decisions for the
0:40:12 benefit of their users and for the benefit of themselves.
0:40:15 And you end up with this very dynamic system where the end users don’t necessarily need
0:40:19 to think about the complexity of the underlying mechanic of the thing.
0:40:24 And importantly, there’s explicit enforceability over one canonical group of contracts that
0:40:26 control the system.
0:40:32 And so the output of the governance process doesn’t require, for example, end users or
0:40:36 other participants in the network to download new software and run it.
0:40:41 The analogy of a blockchain is we’re traveling down a highway.
0:40:47 And then we decide that we want to take a turn, one of two turns into two different futures.
0:40:52 And that will be upgrading– miners upgrade their software to a new fork version.
0:40:57 What forks are in protocols is different than forks are on base layers.
0:41:02 You can’t fork in the case of a stable coin because it has all this collateral.
0:41:06 You can’t fork the collateral because your DAP doesn’t control that.
0:41:09 You are using the existing platforms collateral.
0:41:10 So the upgrade process has to be different.
0:41:14 In the governance debate, there’s nuance in what it means to upgrade a DAP that’s running
0:41:16 on top of ProCo and the protocol itself.
0:41:19 You brought up the example of a computation network.
0:41:22 It’s a very well-defined kind of service.
0:41:24 A computer runs the code, and the code has an output.
0:41:28 If you focus on something more controversial, like how value is distributed, then all of
0:41:30 a sudden you find that the governance is really important.
0:41:37 And I’d also argue that power token voting excludes the needs of miners and the needs
0:41:38 of users.
0:41:39 That depends on how you design it.
0:41:43 If you think of power as a source of value, then you want to make sure that that power
0:41:46 is evenly distributed amongst the participants of the network.
0:41:49 Otherwise, you end up, again, where we are in the modern economy today with very few
0:41:53 people with a lot of power, and most people with not that much power.
0:41:58 So just one thing I wanted to add is that one of the problems with thinking about on-chain
0:42:03 governance as a way for users to actively participate in the evolution of a network
0:42:07 is that in practice, if we look at the real world and how governance systems work, there’s
0:42:09 actually very low participation.
0:42:16 This is because as an individual user, an individual voter, my one vote, my little say doesn’t
0:42:19 have all that much influence on its own.
0:42:22 And so there’s this apathy about participation.
0:42:28 And so a assumption is that when we talk about users affecting or risking together and participating
0:42:33 in governance, is that they have some sort of emotional stake in the outcome of governance
0:42:34 processes.
0:42:41 And that may be the case in very niche applications where users feel a strong affinity to the application
0:42:42 they’re using.
0:42:46 If I don’t have a strong connection to participating in voting, maybe I’d be more likely to sell
0:42:48 my vote to someone who does.
0:42:53 And the result of that is the same risk that Joel described earlier, where the capital
0:42:57 and the currency become disaggregated.
0:42:59 And this could undermine on-chain governance processes.
0:43:03 It’s important to note that on-chain governance is really hard for a number of reasons.
0:43:07 In the context of blockchains, it’s very difficult to know who the participants are.
0:43:12 You can be hundreds of people just by generating multiple keys.
0:43:17 And so when you have this system that is synonymous, it’s difficult to enforce behavior patterns
0:43:22 that lead to good governance, say, in shareholder governance where shareholders are bound by
0:43:23 fiduciary law.
0:43:28 There’s a great post by a researcher at Cornell who we recently had on the podcast named
0:43:32 Phil Diane, and he went deep down the rabbit hole into different attacks that you could
0:43:33 launch.
0:43:34 The rise of dark doubts?
0:43:39 Yeah, the post dives in deep and our podcast does as well on different sort of attacks
0:43:43 that you can launch to bride participants in on-chain governance schemes.
0:43:49 I think a lot of arguments against on-chain governance are kind of primitive in their
0:43:52 thinking around how is that governance applied.
0:43:57 One common element of a lot of the counterarguments is the assumption that governance power is
0:44:02 linear and one token equals one vote, whereas in crypto networks, we have the opportunity
0:44:05 to design much more intricate systems with much more intricate rules.
0:44:09 And so, yes, you can replicate yourself across a thousand different addresses, while you
0:44:15 can make it such that your governance power is amplified if you have all your tokens
0:44:20 in one wallet and so you can make it actually more powerful to basically voluntarily disclose
0:44:24 still within the pseudonymous system how much of the token you have because you get more
0:44:30 power by aggregating your assets together and you can kind of change how the shape of
0:44:35 that curve, depending on the context, you can also do things like look at the age of
0:44:36 an address.
0:44:40 One thing that we learned actually from a non-crypto company that was in the online
0:44:44 community abuse space is that the length an account has been open is the greatest determinant
0:44:45 of whether it’s a troll or not.
0:44:50 And so you can use things like the life span of an account or of a wallet or the tokens
0:44:51 that it received.
0:44:55 And you can even make distinctions around whether the tokens in that wallet were purchased
0:44:58 from an exchange or were received directly through mining.
0:45:02 And you can factor all of those things into how you design, let’s call it your governance
0:45:03 curve.
0:45:07 Maybe those are all examples of on-chain reputation that’s sort of native to the system.
0:45:08 Exactly.
0:45:10 So yeah, thank you guys very much for coming on.
0:45:14 It’s been awesome sort of recapping the space and how it’s evolved over the last few years
0:45:20 and super excited to see how our theses play out over the years going forward.
0:45:21 Well thanks for having us.
with Chris Burniske (@cburniske), Joel Monegro (@jmonegro), Denis Nazarov (@Iiterature), and Jesse Walden (@jessewldn)
When designing cryptonetworks — really, emerging economies — how do we avoid some of the monetary and fiscal policy failings of ”real-world” economies? Like not separating currency and capital, which accelerated and spread economic growth through the former… but also concentrated the latter into the hands of a few? Yet how can we empower users to access capital while also managing risk?
If the promise of cryptonetworks is to better align incentives and value capture, then we can’t make the same mistakes as we did in traditional economies. We also have the chance to do novel things not possible in the physical world, through software. So this episode of the a16z Podcast — featuring voices from Placeholder VC and a16z Crypto — goes deep into the nuances and mechanisms of cryptonetworks, tokens, and decentralized applications at every layer of the ”stack”. Chris Burniske (who has written a lot about financial modeling-influenced frameworks for analyzing crypto) and Joel Monegro (who has written about ”fat protocols”, and once managed the Digital Economy Department at the Ministry of Industry and Commerce of the Dominican Republic) of Placeholder VC discuss and debate all of the above — and more! — with a16z crypto’s Denis Nazarov and Jesse Walden (co-founders of Mediachain, which was acquired by Spotify).
Throughout the history of information technology, we’ve gone from hardware to software, and software to data. So what’s next, what’s the layer above data? The answer is governance — which gives more people a way to participate in decision making around a given network — but the answer for how to implement the best governance isn’t so clear.
-
a16z Podcast: Voting, Security, and Governance in Blockchains and Cryptonetworks
AI transcript
0:00:03 – The content here is for informational purposes only,
0:00:05 should not be taken as legal business tax
0:00:07 or investment advice or be used to evaluate
0:00:10 any investment or security and is not directed
0:00:14 at any investors or potential investors in any A16Z fund.
0:00:18 For more details, please see a16z.com/disclosures.
0:00:22 – Hi everyone, welcome to the A16Z podcast, I’m Sonal.
0:00:25 Today’s episode is all about blockchain-based voting systems
0:00:29 which has implications for crypto economic security
0:00:32 and for governance, especially when you think
0:00:34 about the differences, both good and bad,
0:00:36 between real world and online systems
0:00:38 for coordinating groups of people to vote on something,
0:00:40 whether it’s a decision in a boardroom
0:00:42 or an election or anything else.
0:00:44 This episode was recorded as part
0:00:46 of our New York City podcast road show
0:00:49 and so it features Phil Dayan, a PhD at Cornell Tech,
0:00:51 working with Ari Jules there.
0:00:53 His research focuses on broad questions
0:00:55 of security of distributed systems,
0:00:56 specifically blockchains.
0:00:58 He also wrote a post last year
0:01:00 with Tyler Kell, Ian Mears and Ari Jules
0:01:05 on quote, “On-chain vote buying and the rise of dark DAOs.”
0:01:06 Joining Phil in this hallway style jam
0:01:09 to discuss these topics is Ali Yaya,
0:01:10 who was previously a software engineer
0:01:13 and machine learning researcher at Google X and Google Brain.
0:01:16 He also gave a talk at A16Z Summit on crypto
0:01:18 and the evolution of trust, which you can find
0:01:22 on our website, and he’s a partner on A16Z Crypto.
0:01:24 Speaking of, please note that the content here
0:01:26 is for informational purposes only,
0:01:29 should not be taken as legal business tax
0:01:32 or investment advice, or be used to evaluate
0:01:34 any investment or security and is not directed
0:01:38 at any investors or potential investors in any fund.
0:01:39 For more details, please also see
0:01:42 A16ZCrypto.com/disclosures.
0:01:44 The conversation that follows covers ways
0:01:46 in which blockchain systems are different
0:01:48 from real-world voting systems,
0:01:50 ways the system can be gamed
0:01:52 and what that means for security,
0:01:54 as well as possible solutions
0:01:56 and more importantly, questions
0:01:58 all blockchain system designers should think about
0:02:01 instead of making naive assumptions.
0:02:04 But first, Phil and Ali began by very briefly summing up
0:02:06 the issues in real-world elections
0:02:08 and electronic voting systems.
0:02:11 The first voice you’ll hear is Phil’s, followed by Ali’s.
0:02:14 – So one challenge people have seen is straight up hacking.
0:02:17 Of course, if there is electronic voting in use,
0:02:19 just tampering with the integrity of the election itself
0:02:21 or the integrity of the registration.
0:02:23 Another challenge that people have been worried about
0:02:26 in the past is vote buying and selling.
0:02:27 So if I want you to vote a certain way,
0:02:30 maybe I directly bribe you to do so
0:02:32 or maybe even in the current system,
0:02:34 I can indirectly do it.
0:02:37 But it’s very difficult to bribe someone in person
0:02:39 and sort of understand how they’re going
0:02:40 to act in an election.
0:02:42 – Yeah, you have this great example of how
0:02:44 if the price of a vote is a beer
0:02:45 and you take me out for a beer and say,
0:02:48 “Ali, I want you to vote for ex-candidate.”
0:02:50 I could drink your beer and then go to the poll
0:02:53 and submit whichever ballot I want.
0:02:56 And you have no real mechanism to enforce my vote
0:02:58 in one way or another.
0:03:01 And you then point out how this is not so much the case
0:03:03 when you go to the world of electronic voting.
0:03:04 – Yes, the price of the vote as a beer
0:03:06 is actually kind of realistic.
0:03:09 Like vote buying in general is empirically pretty cheap
0:03:10 for two reasons.
0:03:11 Number one, it’s actually the poorest
0:03:13 and least advantaged people that are the most inclined
0:03:15 to sell their votes.
0:03:17 And number two is most people are disinterested
0:03:18 in most elections.
0:03:20 So this actually makes vote buying pretty cheap.
0:03:22 And in electronic voting, this is a big problem
0:03:25 because with many electronic voting protocols,
0:03:26 you can actually tell at the end of the protocol
0:03:27 how someone voted.
0:03:30 So it becomes much easier for me to bribe you
0:03:31 because I can just say essentially I’ll give you a beer
0:03:34 if I check afterwards and you voted with my candidate
0:03:36 rather than sort of trusting you to go in the polling booth
0:03:38 and make the right decision where socially
0:03:40 I can’t follow you into that booth
0:03:41 and look over your shoulder.
0:03:42 – Exactly.
0:03:44 You point out how in the world of human voting,
0:03:47 there are three things that tend to make vote buying
0:03:48 a little bit more difficult.
0:03:49 And it’s the inefficiencies of the human world
0:03:51 that actually work to your advantage here.
0:03:53 So the first is that in the human world,
0:03:55 it’s a crime to buy votes and that itself
0:03:57 kind of can serve as a deterrent,
0:03:59 which doesn’t really exist so much
0:04:01 in the jurisdiction-less crypto world.
0:04:03 The second one was that ballots
0:04:04 tend to be casted in secrecy.
0:04:06 So there’s no way of me to produce a proof
0:04:08 that I voted in one way or another,
0:04:11 which makes the buying of the vote difficult to enforce.
0:04:13 And the third one you mentioned is that if you tell me
0:04:15 that you’re going to pay me in the future
0:04:16 for voting one direction or another,
0:04:18 I have a hard time trusting you
0:04:20 that you will actually in the end pay me.
0:04:22 And so there’s sort of counterparty risk.
0:04:25 And so in the same way that sort of blockchains
0:04:30 mitigate trust and improve coordination for good purposes,
0:04:34 they can also be used to improve coordination
0:04:36 for sort of malicious purposes.
0:04:38 In this case, vote buying is like a double-edged sword.
0:04:41 Blockchains can be used to increase the efficiency
0:04:44 and effectiveness of bribery and vote buying.
0:04:45 Yes.
0:04:46 In the traditional world,
0:04:48 there’s been a long line of academic research.
0:04:51 So very early on people said we want to vote electronically.
0:04:52 It’ll make tallying cheaper.
0:04:54 It can maybe use cryptography
0:04:55 to increase the integrity of our elections.
0:04:57 So we don’t rely on these pieces of paper
0:05:00 sort of with this weird chain of human custody
0:05:01 and things like that.
0:05:03 But early schemes sort of suffered from this receipt property
0:05:06 where I could produce a proof that like here is the outcome
0:05:09 and here is what I actually voted to lead to this outcome.
0:05:11 So there was a wide range of work early on
0:05:12 on how to sort of solve this issue
0:05:15 and create voting schemes that are receipt free,
0:05:17 which means that after the fact,
0:05:19 I cannot produce a receipt or a proof
0:05:20 to tell you which way I voted.
0:05:22 And it’s sort of equally likely from your perspective
0:05:24 that I voted in any direction.
0:05:27 Later work sort of said that this is not strong enough.
0:05:29 Essentially the high level is
0:05:31 if you’re looking over my shoulder electronically,
0:05:33 like you have a virus on my computer
0:05:35 or you’re just physically looking over my shoulder,
0:05:36 at the time that I’m voting,
0:05:38 even receipt freedom is not enough
0:05:40 because you might be able to see in real time
0:05:42 the direction in which I’m voting
0:05:43 and enforce my vote that way.
0:05:45 So that led to an even stronger property
0:05:46 called coercion resistance,
0:05:48 which is that even if you compromise me
0:05:49 for some period of time,
0:05:52 you still are not able to get me to vote a certain way
0:05:54 in a way that you can trust.
0:05:55 – Yeah, that’s very interesting.
0:05:59 And so let’s connect this to sort of the blockchain world.
0:06:01 These questions of electronic voting have existed
0:06:03 for decades and predate the world
0:06:05 of blockchains and crypto networks.
0:06:07 But now there’s like a resurgence of research
0:06:10 in this direction because so many blockchain
0:06:11 and crypto network projects
0:06:14 want to use on-chain voting for all sorts of purposes.
0:06:16 – So I mean, in blockchain networks in general,
0:06:17 you often need to make decisions.
0:06:20 That’s like part of the attractive point of blockchains
0:06:22 that it makes coordinating group decisions
0:06:24 among actors who don’t trust each other
0:06:26 a little bit easier.
0:06:29 And to make these decisions sort of a natural response
0:06:30 is just vote, right?
0:06:31 That’s something you see in the real world.
0:06:34 It’s something you see in corporations with stockholders.
0:06:35 It’s something you see in boardrooms.
0:06:37 It’s something you see in political elections
0:06:39 and all sorts of other social systems.
0:06:41 So it’s just, I think, a natural human tendency
0:06:43 when asking sort of how to organize these things
0:06:47 that voting is the only real clear shelling point answer
0:06:48 that we can come up with.
0:06:49 So I think an important distinction
0:06:52 on why this stuff really matters in the blockchain world
0:06:54 is that the blockchain world and the real world
0:06:56 don’t operate in the same models.
0:06:57 If you’re going to a boardroom with someone,
0:06:59 you’re sitting next to the person, right?
0:07:02 We’re sort of operating in this model of social honesty
0:07:04 where people can see each other face to face.
0:07:05 You have shared interests in the company.
0:07:08 You sort of know their history at least somewhat.
0:07:10 Whereas in blockchains, you’re operating in an economic,
0:07:13 sort of an economically rational game theoretic model.
0:07:15 So you need much stronger guarantees from your systems.
0:07:17 Your systems need to be strong
0:07:20 even in the presence of economically motivated adversaries.
0:07:21 And they need to be secure,
0:07:24 assuming people are rational rather than honest.
0:07:25 So we don’t get to lean on this sort of honesty
0:07:28 that we have in the real world in blockchains.
0:07:29 And I think that’s where a lot of the mechanisms
0:07:32 that people try to sort of port over naively break down.
0:07:34 – Right, and this is especially important
0:07:36 because in most of the crypto networks
0:07:38 that are actually interesting,
0:07:42 the model is one where anyone can participate.
0:07:44 And people refer to this as the permissionless setting
0:07:46 and that anyone can connect to the network.
0:07:49 Anyone can sort of participate in the decisions
0:07:51 that are made through the governance processes
0:07:53 of the crypto network,
0:07:55 which makes the environment the very hostile one
0:07:57 because anyone anywhere can opt to participate
0:07:59 and they have an economic incentive to do so
0:08:01 because if they can game the system
0:08:03 or if they can sort of subvert it in some way,
0:08:05 then they could potentially profit.
0:08:06 – Exactly.
0:08:08 Satoshi released his white paper in ’09
0:08:10 and academics first started looking at Bitcoin
0:08:12 and its success and its rise
0:08:14 and asking like what is actually the interesting lesson
0:08:16 to be learned here from what we’ve been doing
0:08:17 for the last 20 years.
0:08:19 There was a whole space of consensus protocols
0:08:21 and Byzantine fault-tolerant protocols
0:08:22 that came to consensus on something
0:08:25 even in the presence of malicious users.
0:08:27 But what was really new about Bitcoin
0:08:30 is that it let anyone join and leave the network at any time.
0:08:32 And these people didn’t need to ask the people
0:08:35 who are already participating in the network
0:08:36 whether they can join or not.
0:08:38 So in most consensus protocols,
0:08:40 you have a sort of quorum that’s coming to decisions
0:08:41 and if you want to join,
0:08:43 you need to ask the quorum to join
0:08:45 because the quorum needs to agree on who’s in the quorum.
0:08:46 So they need to sort of come to consensus
0:08:48 on the fact that you’re allowed to join.
0:08:50 Whereas in something like Bitcoin,
0:08:51 if you want to start mining Bitcoin,
0:08:53 you just turn on your rig and as soon as you succeed,
0:08:55 people will accept that mathematically.
0:08:57 They don’t need any sort of membership proof
0:08:58 or anything like that.
0:08:59 What I think is relevant to voting
0:09:01 is that fundamental to the permissionless model
0:09:03 if you’re gonna use cryptography,
0:09:04 which all blockchains do,
0:09:06 is that if I can join and leave at any time,
0:09:08 I need to be able to like generate my own key
0:09:09 and join at any time.
0:09:10 – Right.
0:09:13 I mean, the uses of on-chain voting,
0:09:16 we’re voting within blockchain projects,
0:09:19 range all the way from setting the parameters,
0:09:21 like some parameter in the protocol
0:09:22 that may be something minor,
0:09:25 kind of like the price of gas, for example,
0:09:28 all the way over to sort of some intermediate level
0:09:30 where people use governance
0:09:32 and voting to decide how to allocate funds.
0:09:34 And then this goes all of the way over
0:09:37 to actually deciding how to change the protocol itself.
0:09:40 And so there are projects that are sort of self-amending
0:09:45 and that they use governance as a way of proposing updates
0:09:47 to the protocol and then deciding on which updates
0:09:50 should go through and which updates should not.
0:09:51 And so the stakes are high
0:09:55 and that if you have a governance system that can be gamed,
0:09:59 then all of these use cases may end up being vulnerable
0:10:00 to that kind of attack.
0:10:02 One way of thinking of governance that I quite like
0:10:04 that I think was proposed by Vitalik
0:10:07 is the coordination model of governance
0:10:10 and that really all governance decisions are in essence
0:10:13 a way of coordinating collective action.
0:10:16 He talks about how there are multiple layers
0:10:17 to governance, right?
0:10:19 The bottom layer is like what’s closest
0:10:20 to the real and physical world.
0:10:22 – Yeah, so maybe let’s go bottom up
0:10:24 on everywhere you have voting in blockchains.
0:10:25 At the very base level,
0:10:27 all consensus mechanisms are a vote,
0:10:29 so proof of work itself is a form of voting
0:10:30 on which block is valid
0:10:32 and which history is accepted by the network.
0:10:34 So you have voting at that layer.
0:10:35 Then that half layer up, like you said,
0:10:38 is this governance layer of how do blockchains
0:10:39 actually change their underlying code
0:10:42 and respond to attacks or new situations
0:10:45 or new technology or whatever it may be.
0:10:48 Traditionally, this has sort of gone with the fork model
0:10:50 where you just sort of spin up new code
0:10:52 and try to lobby everyone to just run this new system
0:10:53 instead of the old one.
0:10:55 This model has seen a lot of political strife,
0:10:59 a lot of inefficiency, a lot of sort of lobbying
0:11:01 and traditional politics like nastiness
0:11:03 in the blockchain space.
0:11:06 You can look at the Bitcoin block size debate,
0:11:07 whether to change the one to a two,
0:11:11 which spawned like a year long rift between the communities
0:11:13 that ended up in like several summits and agreements
0:11:16 and eventually a permanent split.
0:11:17 So some people look at that and say,
0:11:18 maybe we can make this more efficient
0:11:20 by just using voting and allowing the coin holders
0:11:22 to express their preference
0:11:23 and sort of just going with that.
0:11:25 And then another layer up from that,
0:11:27 you have the application layers like you were saying.
0:11:30 So these are your DAOs, these are your smart contracts
0:11:32 that wanna use voting to make decisions.
0:11:35 They could be, for example, on how to allocate funds.
0:11:37 They could be on how to change parameters
0:11:38 within their own smart contract.
0:11:41 So you really have voting throughout the blockchain stack.
0:11:42 A lot of projects are using it
0:11:46 and it has a very sort of wide impact as a general problem.
0:11:49 – So one observation that comes out of all of this
0:11:52 is that today’s governance systems
0:11:54 and sort of blockchains and crypto networks,
0:11:56 the way that they exist today will likely devolve
0:11:59 into plutocracy simply because the mechanisms
0:12:02 for vote buying are so effective as you described.
0:12:05 And some proponents of on-chain governance
0:12:07 will argue that plutocracy may not actually
0:12:08 be that bad of a thing.
0:12:10 They may be a bad thing for democracies,
0:12:12 but not so much for blockchains.
0:12:15 In the blockchain world for a crypto network,
0:12:17 it’s not so much a bad thing
0:12:20 because it’s in a sense incentive compatible,
0:12:21 at least at a surface level.
0:12:24 If they are voting using their coins
0:12:26 for any one upgrade to the protocol,
0:12:29 they will want to vote in the interest of other people
0:12:31 who also hold the coins in the interest of the network
0:12:34 because they own it and they have a stake in it.
0:12:37 And also their incentive to protect the network
0:12:38 is proportional to how many coins they own.
0:12:41 So like larger voters or stakeholders
0:12:43 who have more coins in the network
0:12:46 have an even greater incentive to protect the network.
0:12:48 What are your thoughts there?
0:12:49 – So I think every blockchain project
0:12:51 should take a step back and ask,
0:12:52 do we want plutocracy?
0:12:53 Do we want vote buying in our system?
0:12:55 And what are the consequences of that?
0:12:56 For many of them,
0:12:58 maybe it’s more acceptable than for others.
0:13:02 For example, if you have like a small closed sort of contract
0:13:03 that has a few shareholders,
0:13:05 something like an investment firm
0:13:06 and you have like one guy
0:13:08 who decides whether people get in or not,
0:13:10 maybe you’re not so concerned about vote buying
0:13:11 in that kind of a scheme.
0:13:15 Or if you have even like some sort of closed setting
0:13:17 where you can say things about the participants,
0:13:19 maybe you’re not so concerned about vote buying.
0:13:21 In a wider system where let’s say
0:13:23 the whole world is participating in it eventually,
0:13:25 I think the fundamental point is that
0:13:27 most people are disinterested in most votes
0:13:29 and the utility they get from the system
0:13:31 is not directly sort of correlated
0:13:34 with whether they vote A or B on this given issue.
0:13:36 Nonetheless, there are certain groups of people
0:13:37 who are extremely interested
0:13:39 in whether people vote A or B on a certain issue
0:13:41 and these are often pretty moneyed groups.
0:13:42 So in this way,
0:13:44 that kind of governance does sort of degenerate
0:13:45 into plutocracy.
0:13:48 And if that’s acceptable for your system, that’s fine.
0:13:49 I think for many systems, it’s not.
0:13:51 You need to care about these attacks
0:13:52 and you need to reason about
0:13:54 why your system is secure against this
0:13:56 and why your system actually doesn’t degenerate
0:13:57 to plutocracy.
0:13:58 People have tried to get around this
0:14:00 in two ways in blockchains.
0:14:02 The first one is they add some sort of identity.
0:14:03 So they have a third party service
0:14:05 that like you send your cell phone number
0:14:07 or something like that and it sends you a text
0:14:09 and sort of anti-sibles you that way
0:14:11 and then you’re able to participate in a vote.
0:14:15 So at least you can sort of attach some entity
0:14:17 to the person and then count votes per entity
0:14:18 rather than per coin.
0:14:21 This actually still degenerates into plutocracy
0:14:22 because of the way the Dark Dow works
0:14:25 because as long as these identities are keys
0:14:27 that people can sort of generate at any time,
0:14:30 they can be bought and sold and using the Dark Dow model
0:14:31 and you can essentially sell people
0:14:33 like the right to your identity
0:14:35 or you can sell people the right to a certain vote
0:14:38 using your identity or even more specific things than that.
0:14:40 So that kind of doesn’t work
0:14:42 unless you have a strong social protection
0:14:44 where like the person has to come in very often
0:14:46 and the network sort of authenticates
0:14:49 that they’re human or something like that.
0:14:50 That becomes very complicated
0:14:52 and steps much more into the messy world
0:14:53 of real world elections
0:14:56 and maybe doesn’t work for a global blockchain community.
0:14:58 Another way people have tried to get around it
0:15:00 which also kind of requires identity
0:15:03 is this new line of work by Vitalik Glenn Whale
0:15:05 and a few other people which is quadratic voting
0:15:07 where you actually allow vote buying.
0:15:09 So you allow people to buy votes
0:15:11 but only at an exponentially increasing price.
0:15:13 And this may kind of look like plutocracy
0:15:15 because you’re allowing people to buy votes
0:15:17 but if you actually do the math on the incentives,
0:15:20 it turns out that through this increasing function,
0:15:21 essentially people will express
0:15:22 their true preferences in the end.
0:15:26 And one rich person who really cares about A versus B
0:15:29 won’t be able to sort of overwhelm a disinterested majority
0:15:30 that weakly prefers A
0:15:32 and maybe each don’t have as many funds
0:15:33 as that one individual.
0:15:35 So this fixes some known pathologies
0:15:37 in real world voting systems
0:15:39 and also blockchain voting systems.
0:15:41 But it does require identity
0:15:43 and it’s extremely vulnerable to manipulation.
0:15:45 If this one rich person can pretend
0:15:47 that they’re two rich people or something like that,
0:15:48 the gig is sort of up.
0:15:51 And that’s what these new coordination mechanisms allow.
0:15:53 – Yes, I think this dependence on identity
0:15:55 that you are pointing out is very important
0:15:57 because as you pointed out,
0:15:59 anyone can pretend to be more than one person.
0:16:02 They can generate 10 different sets of key pairs
0:16:03 or hundreds of sets of key pairs
0:16:05 and pretend to be hundreds of people.
0:16:06 – Yeah, and the only thing you can do
0:16:07 is wait by coins basically.
0:16:08 – Exactly.
0:16:10 In that world, you end up with unfair representation
0:16:13 of you’re trying to assign a single vote to a key pair.
0:16:17 So proponents of on-chain coin holder governance
0:16:21 which means that one coin gives you one vote will argue.
0:16:23 It’s at the very least, civil resistant,
0:16:26 which means that if you have like 10 million coins
0:16:28 staked on one particular vote,
0:16:31 they’re basically used to vote for one particular outcome.
0:16:34 It’s very hard to argue that those 10 million coins
0:16:37 come from trolls that are trying to sway the election
0:16:39 because there’s real weight and real capital
0:16:41 that’s staked in one direction or another.
0:16:43 Whereas if you’re not using coin voting,
0:16:45 then that becomes more possible.
0:16:48 And so if you have a mechanism for identity
0:16:52 wherein you securely associate one human to one vote
0:16:53 or something like that,
0:16:57 then more sophisticated voting schemes become possible.
0:17:00 I think today, because we lack that kind of a mechanism,
0:17:03 people end up gravitating towards this simple
0:17:07 and somewhat, perhaps somewhat naive one coin, one vote model
0:17:09 which is vulnerable to this foot buying attack.
0:17:13 – Yeah, and this opens up a range of other issues.
0:17:15 So one problem that people have
0:17:16 when they analyze blockchain systems
0:17:18 and they sort of design these mechanisms
0:17:19 is that they look at their mechanism
0:17:21 and reason about its security properties,
0:17:23 but they do that in isolation.
0:17:25 And an important point is that none of these systems
0:17:27 really exist in a vacuum, right?
0:17:29 So take a look at any sort of blockchain
0:17:31 that uses coinholder voting to decide
0:17:33 the outcome of its consensus rules.
0:17:35 And there’s at least two such blockchains
0:17:37 that are sort of using this model.
0:17:39 If these two very large projects are approximately
0:17:41 the same size or one is a little bit bigger
0:17:43 than the other one or one is twice as big
0:17:45 as the other one or something like that,
0:17:47 it’s in the economic interests of everyone
0:17:49 who holds coins in the bigger project
0:17:51 to buy up coins on the smaller project
0:17:53 and influence votes in ways
0:17:55 that are sort of counter competitive.
0:17:57 And maybe even if they can’t buy up
0:17:58 enough of a blocked influence votes,
0:18:02 they can sow chaos and confusion and things like that.
0:18:05 So while one of these systems, you may say in isolation,
0:18:07 like, okay, the coinholders interests are represented
0:18:09 by this plutocracy, that doesn’t really work
0:18:11 when you have a whole world around it
0:18:13 that’s full of money that can frictionlessly
0:18:15 enter and exit the system at any time.
0:18:17 There’s no guarantee whatsoever
0:18:19 that the people who are economically in right this second
0:18:21 have an interest in that system,
0:18:22 especially when there are much bigger systems
0:18:24 that are competing with it.
0:18:25 So I think that’s a very important point
0:18:26 that people overlook.
0:18:28 And again, we mentioned that there’s this sort of stack
0:18:30 of voting, even at the consensus layer,
0:18:32 that has implications on the whole stack.
0:18:34 So if you have a fork that’s like 10%
0:18:36 of the size of a project,
0:18:38 and this fork could potentially impact
0:18:40 the price of the larger project,
0:18:42 it’s absolutely in the interest of that larger project
0:18:45 to launch attacks on that base layer proof of workflow
0:18:46 and do things like censorship,
0:18:48 use some small percentage of their hash power
0:18:51 to do 51% attacks or denial of service
0:18:52 or whatever they need to do to make sure
0:18:54 that that network goes down in price.
0:18:56 And that attack might even be profitable,
0:18:58 especially if there are mechanisms to short
0:18:59 that sort of smaller project.
0:19:00 – Yeah, that’s a very good point.
0:19:03 I think most proponents of a coinholder voting
0:19:07 would argue that it is just not in your interest
0:19:10 to sell your vote because you’d be damaging
0:19:11 the value of the asset that you hold.
0:19:14 And you hold a coin, and if you sell the votes
0:19:15 associated with that coin,
0:19:17 and that might reduce the value of the coin
0:19:20 in some way that sort of results in a net loss for you.
0:19:22 But that analysis happens entirely in a vacuum.
0:19:26 It happens sort of assuming that there aren’t any kind
0:19:28 of external mechanisms via which you could profit
0:19:31 from the loss of value of this particular coin.
0:19:32 Like for example, what you’re mentioning,
0:19:33 competition between blockchains.
0:19:36 If I’m a stakeholder, a much larger stakeholder
0:19:37 in a competing network,
0:19:39 then I might have a strong interest
0:19:41 in reducing the value of this particular coin,
0:19:42 and that that’s associated
0:19:44 with this one competing crypto network
0:19:46 because it may result in a larger profit
0:19:48 outside of the system.
0:19:51 And so I think, yeah, the incentive structures
0:19:53 that are built in aggregate tend to be far more complex
0:19:55 and they kind of interact in ways
0:19:58 that tend to be difficult to analyze
0:19:59 and could result in complexity
0:20:01 that could ultimately result in attacks.
0:20:03 And you post, you talk a little bit
0:20:05 about what you refer to as the dark DAO,
0:20:07 which sounds like a fairly dark picture
0:20:10 of what could end up being the case.
0:20:11 In your view, what is the worst case scenario here?
0:20:14 How could this unfold in a bad way?
0:20:15 – Yeah, so there’s a lot of different variants
0:20:17 of the dark DAO which have different assumptions
0:20:19 in the post, some of them require trusted hardware,
0:20:20 some of them don’t.
0:20:22 But the ultimate point of the dark DAO
0:20:23 is that it’s a private smart contract
0:20:26 for attacking a vote, for vote buying,
0:20:28 that essentially hides from the rest of the world
0:20:30 how much money is committed to this contract,
0:20:33 who is participating in the vote buying contract,
0:20:35 and sort of how far along the contract is.
0:20:37 But sort of is a way to frictionlessly
0:20:40 and permissionlessly form a vote buying cartel
0:20:41 for a particular vote.
0:20:42 And this could be sort of a funding pool,
0:20:44 anyone can come contribute money to it.
0:20:45 So if it’s outcome specific,
0:20:47 it could be funded by anyone who’s interested
0:20:48 in such an outcome,
0:20:50 whether it be other blockchain projects,
0:20:53 users on the system, outside groups, whatever it may be.
0:20:55 So once this dark DAO is funded,
0:20:57 what it does is sort of offer up vote buying
0:20:58 to people in the system.
0:21:01 And if people in the system come take this vote buying,
0:21:02 they retain access to their funds,
0:21:05 they keep using their wallet as they normally do,
0:21:07 but they’re sort of shackled by the dark DAO
0:21:08 that for this particular vote,
0:21:10 they can only vote in this certain way.
0:21:10 And this is trustless
0:21:12 because both sides have some guarantees.
0:21:16 So the vote buyers or vote buying network
0:21:18 or whatever it may be has guarantees
0:21:19 that potentially no one will find out
0:21:21 who’s being bought or sold
0:21:23 and how much money is pledged to it.
0:21:24 They’re guaranteed that if they pay for a vote,
0:21:27 this vote will actually be executed in the protocol,
0:21:29 even if the protocol does have
0:21:31 the classic properties of coercion resistance.
0:21:33 Another sort of sidebar of the dark DAO
0:21:36 is that trusted hardware, which is a new technology,
0:21:38 sort of breaks all classical coercion resistance voting
0:21:40 schemes in the blockchain world
0:21:42 and in the regular election world.
0:21:43 So once they launch this attack
0:21:45 and they start buying and selling people’s votes,
0:21:47 they have a number of options available to them.
0:21:48 One cool thing you can do
0:21:50 is you can tell everyone in the cartel
0:21:52 when a certain threshold is reached.
0:21:54 Let’s say when like 70% of the,
0:21:57 or 10% of the votes are locked into this DAO.
0:21:59 And you can do this in a way that’s deniable
0:22:01 such that everyone inside the cartel can check,
0:22:03 yes, 70% is reached,
0:22:05 but no one outside the cartel has any way of knowing
0:22:07 that this is actually reached.
0:22:09 So you can enforce an information asymmetry
0:22:12 that allows for profiting through things like shorting.
0:22:14 You can also enforce stronger information asymmetries,
0:22:16 so not even allow the people who are being bribed
0:22:19 to know at any time how much money is in it
0:22:23 or even potentially whether they voted at all
0:22:25 if the scheme is receipt free.
0:22:27 So it’s a very, very powerful class of attack.
0:22:29 You can spin it up however you want.
0:22:31 It allows people to pool their money and buy votes
0:22:34 in a way that they can keep any part of that secret
0:22:35 to any group of people that they want.
0:22:37 And the outside system has no way of knowing
0:22:39 sort of how far along the attack is.
0:22:41 In some ways, it also represents a credible threat.
0:22:42 If I were to launch a dark DAO,
0:22:44 I might not even need to necessarily have people
0:22:45 participate in it.
0:22:47 Just its existence might be enough
0:22:50 to shake people’s confidence in that underlying vote.
0:22:52 So when we publish that blog post,
0:22:54 we’ve had a lot of reactions from voting projects
0:22:55 and other people in the space.
0:22:57 And I think there is a good question
0:22:58 of why haven’t we seen this already?
0:23:01 But at the end of the day, these systems are tiny, right?
0:23:03 Blockchains today are a drop in the bucket
0:23:05 of like the world financial system
0:23:07 and the incentives just aren’t there yet.
0:23:08 But if we are to use these technologies
0:23:10 and if we are to scale things,
0:23:13 I think these are absolutely realistic scenarios
0:23:15 and potentially nightmare scenarios.
0:23:16 – Yeah, that sounds insane.
0:23:18 And that’s definitely an outcome that is to be prevented.
0:23:21 And I think, I mean, this matters because
0:23:24 if we just take a step back and think about why is governance
0:23:26 so topical and so important in the world of crypto
0:23:27 and blockchains today?
0:23:32 It is because so much of what drives the space forward
0:23:35 in what is sort of the underlying philosophical motivation
0:23:39 is that power over these networks is decentralized.
0:23:41 And so decentralization here refers to
0:23:42 a bunch of different things at the same time.
0:23:44 Like people talk about decentralization
0:23:46 as it refers to sort of consensus,
0:23:50 like who gets to decide like who modifies
0:23:51 the underlying ledger,
0:23:52 but also decentralization applies
0:23:54 to who gets to modify the code.
0:23:56 These networks are decentralized in that
0:23:58 they’re kind of like self-governing organizations
0:24:00 and they don’t have at least philosophically
0:24:03 any central points of control where any one individual
0:24:06 can decide how to sort of modify the code
0:24:08 or make it work in any particular way.
0:24:12 And so all of these initiatives to try to build in governance
0:24:15 into the protocols are an effort to try to
0:24:17 sort of decentralize even that aspect
0:24:20 and to try to make it so that the code itself can evolve
0:24:22 in a way that is still community driven
0:24:24 and not kind of centrally controlled
0:24:27 by the core developer team.
0:24:28 – Yeah, I think the promise of a lot of these systems
0:24:31 is sort of this crypto economic security, right?
0:24:33 You have this mechanism and because the mechanism works
0:24:34 and the incentives are set up right,
0:24:36 everyone comes together harmoniously
0:24:38 and produces something that is bulletproof
0:24:42 and very strong because of the incentives and the mechanism.
0:24:43 An example of this is Bitcoin.
0:24:45 Because of the money paid to miners,
0:24:48 people are burning a small country’s worth of electricity
0:24:50 to try to secure this transaction ledger
0:24:52 that has actually worked fantastically so far.
0:24:53 So when you design these systems,
0:24:56 there needs to be some sort of underlying mechanism
0:24:57 and some sort of reasoning about the security
0:24:59 of that mechanism.
0:25:01 But what these technologies like the dark dial
0:25:03 and private smart contracts allow you to do
0:25:06 is use external money to sort of alter the incentives
0:25:09 inside that game and alter the security properties
0:25:12 that people are actually getting from their project
0:25:15 in a permissionless and trustless way.
0:25:17 So this does sort of speak
0:25:20 to the fundamental coordination of blockchains, right?
0:25:23 Like how do we design these games to coordinate people
0:25:26 to make choices in a way that’s not controlled
0:25:28 by one particular individual, as you said,
0:25:30 or some social trust hierarchy,
0:25:32 but by the economics of the system itself?
0:25:33 And in that model,
0:25:35 if you can’t be secure against economic attacks,
0:25:38 then you’re sort of building something
0:25:40 that doesn’t make much sense in my opinion.
0:25:43 And so I guess that’s a lot of what my work is looking at.
0:25:45 – Right, what do you think are the implications
0:25:47 of vote buying on proof of stake?
0:25:50 – So proof of work is where people use hardware
0:25:51 to sort of solve hard problems.
0:25:53 And if they solve the problem,
0:25:55 then they can post a block to the network.
0:25:56 Rather than using this mechanism,
0:25:59 proof of stake allows people to vote using their coins.
0:26:01 So they lock up their coins for some long period of time
0:26:04 and they can use any number of protocols to do this.
0:26:07 The core idea here is that instead of proof of work
0:26:09 where the economic security you get
0:26:12 is because people are doing this useless computation problem
0:26:13 that is sort of burning money
0:26:16 and there’s some costs associated with doing this,
0:26:18 is that people are paying liquidity costs
0:26:20 to lock up these coins for a long, long period of time
0:26:22 and they’re also taking risks
0:26:23 that they may incur penalties
0:26:25 if they misbehave in the protocol.
0:26:27 And with these liquidity costs,
0:26:28 they’re taking like massive volatility risks
0:26:30 in cryptocurrencies, right?
0:26:32 So if they do something that crashes the system,
0:26:33 well, their coins are locked up
0:26:34 and they’re going to lose money.
0:26:36 If the network decides they misbehaved,
0:26:38 well, they can get rid of all their coins
0:26:39 and they’re gonna lose money.
0:26:40 So it’s this idea of bootstrapping
0:26:42 the economic security of the network from the coins
0:26:45 rather than from some external hardware source.
0:26:46 Obviously that comes with a lot of trade-offs
0:26:48 that are maybe beyond the scope of this discussion,
0:26:50 but at the end of the day, it’s also a voting protocol.
0:26:53 You have these people with coins, they decide how to vote.
0:26:55 So where does vote buying come in here?
0:26:57 Well, obviously this proof-of-stake protocol has an outcome.
0:27:00 It decides what history of the network is valid
0:27:02 and this outcome has all sorts of economic implications.
0:27:05 It decides who gets to send money to who.
0:27:07 It decides who is censored in the system.
0:27:10 It decides what order transactions happen in canonically
0:27:12 according to everyone in the system
0:27:14 and with that comes a lot of profit opportunity.
0:27:17 So I can potentially profit by censoring you
0:27:19 or I can profit by putting my transactions in front of yours
0:27:22 when you wanna execute an order on a decentralized exchange
0:27:25 or I can profit in sort of any number of different ways
0:27:26 by manipulating this vote.
0:27:28 So what you can do with the dark DAO
0:27:30 is to start a staking pool where I say like,
0:27:32 you know, let me do my algorithmic trading
0:27:34 and decide what order of transactions
0:27:35 makes me the most money.
0:27:36 You don’t necessarily care
0:27:38 if someone who’s doing a transaction on a dex
0:27:40 gets front-run and loses like $5, right?
0:27:43 So you say, okay, I’ll happily participate in this.
0:27:45 It’ll still keep the value of my coins high,
0:27:46 especially if I don’t have a lot of coins
0:27:48 and you’re paying me like twice as much
0:27:50 as any other staking pool.
0:27:52 So it sort of opens these coordination mechanisms
0:27:54 for attacks on the underlying transaction history
0:27:56 and the underlying consensus.
0:27:56 – Do you think that there’s a way
0:27:59 of making a proof-of-stake network secure?
0:28:01 – It depends on your definition of secure.
0:28:04 I think it really depends on the type of security you want,
0:28:05 I guess.
0:28:07 – Yeah, and this all gets to the broader question
0:28:10 of like economic security of a blockchain.
0:28:11 And in the case of proof-of-stake,
0:28:13 the resource that’s used to secure the blockchain
0:28:14 is internal to the network.
0:28:15 In the case of proof-of-work,
0:28:18 it’s sort of electricity and like hardware
0:28:21 that’s used external to the network to secure the ledger.
0:28:22 And there are many other kind of approaches.
0:28:26 Like people are experimenting with doing useful work.
0:28:28 Instead of burning electricity uselessly
0:28:30 as you do in proof-of-work,
0:28:32 people try to build a sort of proof-of-space
0:28:34 or proof-of-spacetime protocols
0:28:39 where like for example, you’re able to store files
0:28:41 and storage becomes the resource that people use
0:28:43 to then secure the network.
0:28:44 What do you think of that kind of approach?
0:28:46 – So fundamentally to vote buying,
0:28:48 it doesn’t actually matter what resource you’re using.
0:28:50 Vote buying works for proof-of-work too.
0:28:52 So I could use dark DAO like technology
0:28:53 to start the mining pool.
0:28:55 And the properties of the mining pool would be
0:28:56 you come, you mine here.
0:28:57 I’ll pay you more than we’re making
0:28:59 because I have some external incentive
0:29:02 to censor someone or reorder transactions or whatever.
0:29:04 And then you get the dark DAO privacy properties
0:29:06 of no one knows how much hash power is participating
0:29:09 in this pool or who’s getting paid or things like that.
0:29:11 So these certainly also apply to systems
0:29:15 that use things like files and other useful work properties.
0:29:17 I think there’s a whole class of other questions
0:29:19 on the economic security of those systems.
0:29:21 So you have to be really careful
0:29:23 about where the economic security comes from.
0:29:24 I think you have to be really careful
0:29:26 with what useful means.
0:29:28 Whether the fact that it’s useful also introduces
0:29:31 any external incentives to mess with it, right?
0:29:35 So you could imagine like if the useful thing
0:29:37 the network was doing was like powering a search engine
0:29:38 or something, right?
0:29:39 Those results are valuable
0:29:42 and they bring external actors in who want to manipulate that.
0:29:43 And there’s sort of this feedback loop
0:29:45 between the mechanism securing the protocol
0:29:48 and the utility of what the protocol is actually providing.
0:29:50 But there’s definitely some people in the community
0:29:53 that look at that and say this is all way too complicated.
0:29:54 This is never going to work.
0:29:55 You have to have it be useless
0:29:57 because there’s no external incentives
0:29:59 and messy things that way.
0:30:02 I personally think that’s an open question.
0:30:03 – Yeah, there’s this argument that people make
0:30:06 that if the resource that is used to secure the network
0:30:08 is very commoditized
0:30:09 and just generally exists in the world
0:30:12 in the world in sort of plentiful quantities
0:30:13 that for example, in the case of storage,
0:30:16 if storage is the resource that’s used to secure the network
0:30:17 then anyone with a bunch of storage
0:30:19 could presumably attack the network.
0:30:22 Whereas in the case of a network like say Bitcoin
0:30:25 where you have ASICs that are specific to the network
0:30:27 in order to attack the network
0:30:28 you have to get your hands on those ASICs
0:30:30 and those ASICs aren’t useful for anything
0:30:31 but mining Bitcoin.
0:30:35 So people would argue the security of that kind of
0:30:38 the economic security of that kind of model is better.
0:30:40 – Yeah, and Joe Bono has a fascinating line of work
0:30:41 on these problems.
0:30:42 So if you Google Goldfinger attacks
0:30:44 he has a paper and a presentation.
0:30:47 There’s also the question of like buying versus renting.
0:30:48 So if something is very commoditized
0:30:50 you may be able to rent it
0:30:52 which substantially subsidizes the tax.
0:30:54 You may be able to buy it, perform the attack
0:30:56 and then resell it into the commodity market
0:30:59 which again substantially subsidizes the attack.
0:31:02 So these are all open and very complex questions
0:31:04 but people will build the systems and we’ll see.
0:31:06 This is sort of a classic pattern you see
0:31:08 in traditional finance.
0:31:10 And then you’ll have sort of black swan
0:31:13 and tail risk like events that surprise people.
0:31:15 – So we’ve talked a lot about governance in general
0:31:19 but you obviously are working on a ton of interesting stuff
0:31:21 just generally with respect to economic security
0:31:23 for crypto networks and blockchain
0:31:24 just the computer security.
0:31:27 What are some of the other interesting ideas
0:31:29 or sort of lines of work that you’re exploring?
0:31:32 – So one that I’m extremely personally interested in
0:31:35 is fairness guarantees for users around these systems.
0:31:36 A lot of what attracted me to them in the first place
0:31:39 was this promise of sort of eliminating the middleman
0:31:41 and making things in control of the user.
0:31:43 Like be your own bank, you don’t need these institutions
0:31:45 to tell you how to set your money supply
0:31:47 or how to route your transactions
0:31:50 or what exchange to use, et cetera, et cetera.
0:31:52 I look a lot at those guarantees
0:31:54 and sort of the ways in which modern blockchain solutions
0:31:56 are failing to meet those guarantees.
0:31:59 So one example of that is in the decentralized exchange space.
0:32:01 That’s something that’s seen a lot of promise
0:32:03 from people who wanna build these exchanges
0:32:06 that aren’t vulnerable to hacks and other user fund theft.
0:32:08 Unfortunately, the way these mechanisms
0:32:10 that people are building interact with the blockchain
0:32:13 is very complex and opens the door for external actors
0:32:15 to make a lot of money from front running them
0:32:17 and make a lot of money from doing algorithmic trading
0:32:19 on the network and everything that you see
0:32:21 in the traditional financial world.
0:32:24 So some of my work is around how large is that economy
0:32:27 and what are the failures of those guarantees?
0:32:30 – What are some interesting results so far on that front?
0:32:33 – So it’s actually probably a bigger market than you think,
0:32:36 even though DEXs have not seen substantial volume.
0:32:38 So this is a big problem for users.
0:32:41 It also highlights a lot of weird quirks of these systems,
0:32:44 such as like allowing for typos that end up costing users
0:32:47 a lot of money when programmatic actors soup in
0:32:50 and sort of take advantage of these inefficient mechanisms.
0:32:53 And it also raises fundamental questions about, I guess,
0:32:55 whether we’ll be able to do something that’s different
0:32:57 from the current financial system
0:32:59 because there are still these information asymmetries
0:33:01 that come up and this is a worldwide network.
0:33:02 And at the end of the day,
0:33:04 someone is still ordering transactions.
0:33:07 So is this rent sort of implicit to all blockchains?
0:33:09 How large is it?
0:33:12 And does it threaten the security of the overall blockchain?
0:33:13 Which I think it may.
0:33:15 – So I think one very interesting line of work
0:33:18 that you did was around gas token
0:33:20 and tokenizing gas on the Ethereum network.
0:33:23 – So this sort of came out of this arbitrage project.
0:33:25 We wrote a blog post very early on,
0:33:27 last I think October, November,
0:33:29 essentially saying decentralized exchanges are flawed.
0:33:31 You can just run this 20 line Python script
0:33:33 and you can profit off of users in a way
0:33:34 that was maybe not foreseen
0:33:37 and is not sort of explicitly stated to them
0:33:39 because of how inefficient these mechanisms are.
0:33:40 And before we wrote this blog post,
0:33:42 we were actually doing this to test it, right?
0:33:44 And we said, we made X dollars, whatever.
0:33:45 After we wrote the blog post,
0:33:47 sort of this cottage industry spawned
0:33:50 of like a few dozen people who are competing
0:33:53 in sort of this market and trying to outbid each other
0:33:57 to get their transactions first in that mind order
0:33:59 and take advantage of these opportunities.
0:34:00 So we’ve been studying that market for quite a while
0:34:02 and competing against these guys.
0:34:04 And unfortunately at some point,
0:34:05 they started out competing us.
0:34:07 So we started competing on what’s called gas,
0:34:08 which is the price you’re willing to pay
0:34:10 per unit of transaction.
0:34:12 The way it works is you make a typo Ali,
0:34:14 it puts a million dollars on the table
0:34:16 for anyone who can get their order in ahead of that typo
0:34:18 and sort of take advantage of your typo.
0:34:20 And then I would like to do a $5 transaction
0:34:23 to take advantage of Ali’s mistake, right?
0:34:26 And then maybe someone else is willing
0:34:27 to do a $10 transaction
0:34:29 ’cause it’s a million dollar opportunity, right?
0:34:31 So we sort of get into this bidding war of like,
0:34:33 minor, please pick me first, minor, please pick me first.
0:34:35 That’s inherent to how these transactions
0:34:36 are ordered by miners.
0:34:38 And what we noticed is that when you have like 10 of these,
0:34:39 we were rarely profiting
0:34:40 because we didn’t have the best latency,
0:34:42 we didn’t have the best infrastructure
0:34:44 and they were getting their bids out faster.
0:34:46 They were getting them two miners faster
0:34:48 and they were willing to bid up higher than we were
0:34:50 to essentially take these opportunities.
0:34:51 So that’s where gas token came in.
0:34:54 It’s a way to sort of store this gas for the longer term
0:34:57 rather than just paying for it when you do your transaction.
0:34:59 So gas is the transaction fee.
0:35:00 And usually you say, okay,
0:35:03 I’m willing to pay a $100 fee for this transaction.
0:35:05 Instead, what you could do is sort of bank
0:35:06 a transaction’s worth of gas
0:35:08 and then just deploy that bank gas
0:35:09 and not pay as much fee
0:35:11 for the transaction you are doing.
0:35:12 And that works by taking advantage
0:35:16 of this fundamental issue in Ethereum’s resource model
0:35:18 which has to do with how you pay
0:35:22 to sort of incentivize people to clean up after themselves.
0:35:24 So in Ethereum, you actually give people a refund in gas
0:35:27 if they delete something they stored in the network previously
0:35:29 to incentivize them to not leave garbage around
0:35:30 that everyone has to store forever.
0:35:32 So what we do is when gas is cheap,
0:35:35 we fill the Ethereum state with junk
0:35:36 and then when it’s expensive, we delete this junk
0:35:39 which gives us a refund at that higher price
0:35:42 that we can use to subsidize these arbitrage transactions
0:35:44 which often costs thousands and thousands of dollars in fees.
0:35:47 Like people are bidding multiple thousands,
0:35:49 even tens of thousands in fees on these transactions.
0:35:51 – Right, and so to clarify for those not already familiar,
0:35:54 so gas is basically the resource that you use
0:35:56 to pay for computational resources
0:35:57 on the Ethereum blockchain.
0:36:00 So if you want it to buy computations, say instructions
0:36:03 that miners will execute for you, you pay for those in gas.
0:36:05 If you want it to buy a storage,
0:36:08 you similarly also pay for storage in gas.
0:36:10 And the current model of Ethereum is that you buy
0:36:14 some storage on the blockchain for a fixed price upfront
0:36:16 and then that storage sort of remains
0:36:18 on the blockchain forever.
0:36:20 And the Ethereum blockchain has this mechanism
0:36:22 that if you were to delete that storage,
0:36:23 if you were to free it,
0:36:26 then you will receive a refund for the amount that you paid.
0:36:30 Some refund for what you paid originally
0:36:31 for that amount of storage.
0:36:35 And so you’re basically saying that when gas is very cheap,
0:36:38 you can sort of fill storage on the blockchain
0:36:42 and then reclaim a refund later once gas is expensive.
0:36:45 And sort of the gas will be worth more at that point
0:36:47 than it was when you stored it.
0:36:48 And you could sort of leverage that
0:36:50 to kind of increase the amount of gas
0:36:51 that’s available to you.
0:36:53 – Yeah, and our fundamental observation was that
0:36:54 this is basically a derivative on gas.
0:36:57 It’s like a call option on some gas.
0:36:58 It led to the broader question
0:37:00 of how are these resources actually priced?
0:37:03 Like how do people choose how much is paid for storage?
0:37:06 How do people choose how much is paid for computation?
0:37:07 And in what ways are these suboptimal?
0:37:10 – So you mentioned the current model of pay one store forever.
0:37:12 That’s something we certainly address in our work,
0:37:14 proposing more of a rentful scheme
0:37:17 where you have to pay for ongoing costs at market rate.
0:37:19 There’s also the issue of who’s getting the payment.
0:37:21 So the fact that the miners get payment for storage
0:37:24 when the miners actually don’t need to store the whole state
0:37:26 and it’s the full nodes that bear the cost.
0:37:29 So this sort of asymmetry between who’s bearing the cost
0:37:31 like where the externality is
0:37:32 and like who’s actually profiting
0:37:34 is super important to study.
0:37:36 It leads to a sort of tragedy of the commons
0:37:38 in the worst case where the miners are happy to take payment
0:37:40 for as much storage as you want
0:37:42 because they don’t have to store it and they don’t care.
0:37:43 As long as they don’t break the whole network,
0:37:46 they’ll happily push out as many full nodes as they can.
0:37:47 So these are broader questions.
0:37:50 We have a broader initiative called Project Chicago,
0:37:53 which you can see at projectchicago.io.
0:37:55 That basically is studying these questions
0:37:56 of crypto commodities.
0:37:59 What are the underlying commodities behind blockchains?
0:38:02 For example, computation, relay network and storage.
0:38:03 How are these commodities priced?
0:38:05 How can you exploit these commodities?
0:38:07 How can you exploit like the relay network
0:38:09 to get information about people’s transactions earlier
0:38:13 or the computation layer to sort of, I don’t know,
0:38:16 do this kind of gas refund or something like that.
0:38:19 So there’s a lot of interesting work in that direction.
0:38:21 – Yeah, by the way, why is it called Project Chicago?
0:38:23 – So it’s called Project Chicago
0:38:25 ’cause our inspiration is sort of the Chicago mercantile
0:38:26 exchange.
0:38:28 That’s how businesses hedge against volatility
0:38:31 and sort of price commodities in real world markets.
0:38:35 So we think of this as sort of exploring something similar
0:38:36 on blockchains and asking like,
0:38:38 is that the right model or can we do better
0:38:40 now that we have all these decentralized tools
0:38:41 at our disposal?
0:38:42 – Best painting.
0:38:44 Well, thank you so much for coming on the podcast.
0:38:46 – Yeah, thanks for having me.
with Phil Daian (@phildaian) and Ali Yahya (@ali01)
Whether in corporations, boardrooms, or political elections, voting is something we see in all kinds of social systems… including blockchains. It’s the natural human tendency for how to organize decisions, and in distributed systems without centralized middlemen, it’s the only clear Schelling point we can come up with.
But too many people design voting mechanisms in distributed systems in isolation — sometimes naively ”porting over” assumptions from the real world or from simple cryptoeconomic models without thinking through the economic adversaries present in a larger, more rational (vs. ”honest”) game-theoretic system. So how are blockchain systems different from real-world paper and electronic voting systems? How can such systems be gamed, and what are the implications for cryptoeconomic security… as well as the governance of distributed organizations?
This hallway-style episode of the a16z Podcast covers all this and more. Recorded as part of our NYC roadtrip, it features Cornell Tech PhD student and software engineer Phil Daian, who researches applied cryptography and smart contracts — and who also wrote about ”On-chain Vote Buying and the Rise of Dark DAOs” in 2018 (with Tyler Kell, Ian Miers, and his advisor Ari Juels). Daian is joined by a16z crypto partner Ali Yahya (previously a software engineer and machine learning researcher at GoogleX and Google Brain), who also recently presented on crypto as the evolution — and future — of trust.
The views expressed here are those of the individual AH Capital Management, L.L.C. (“a16z”) personnel quoted and are not the views of a16z or its affiliates. Certain information contained in here has been obtained from third-party sources, including from portfolio companies of funds managed by a16z. While taken from sources believed to be reliable, a16z has not independently verified such information and makes no representations about the enduring accuracy of the information or its appropriateness for a given situation.
This content is provided for informational purposes only, and should not be relied upon as legal, business, investment, or tax advice. You should consult your own advisers as to those matters. References to any securities or digital assets are for illustrative purposes only, and do not constitute an investment recommendation or offer to provide investment advisory services. Furthermore, this content is not directed at nor intended for use by any investors or prospective investors, and may not under any circumstances be relied upon when making a decision to invest in any fund managed by a16z. (An offering to invest in an a16z fund will be made only by the private placement memorandum, subscription agreement, and other relevant documentation of any such fund and should be read in their entirety.) Any investments or portfolio companies mentioned, referred to, or described are not representative of all investments in vehicles managed by a16z, and there can be no assurance that the investments will be profitable or that other investments made in the future will have similar characteristics or results. A list of investments made by funds managed by Andreessen Horowitz (excluding investments and certain publicly traded cryptocurrencies/ digital assets for which the issuer has not provided permission for a16z to disclose publicly) is available at https://a16z.com/investments/.
Charts and graphs provided within are for informational purposes solely and should not be relied upon when making any investment decision. Past performance is not indicative of future results. The content speaks only as of the date indicated. Any projections, estimates, forecasts, targets, prospects, and/or opinions expressed in these materials are subject to change without notice and may differ or be contrary to opinions expressed by others. Please see https://a16z.com/disclosures for additional important information.